67
Abstract
is chapter proposes a direct payment to individuals that would
automatically be paid out early in a recession and then continue annually
when the recession is severe. Research shows that stimulus payments that
were broadly disbursed on an ad hoc (or discretionary) basis in the 2001 and
2008–9 recessions raised consumer spending and helped counteract weak
demand. Making the payments automatic by tying their disbursement to
recent changes in the unemployment rate would ensure that the stimulus
reaches the economy as quickly as possible. A rapid, vigorous response to
the next recession in the form of direct payments to individuals would help
limit employment losses and the economic damage from the recession.
Introduction
Direct payments to individuals are an eective way to stimulate spending
and making these payments automatic would guarantee that stimulus
arrives early in a recession. ese two arguments are supported by a growing
body of high-quality research on the eects of stimulus to individuals
in the past two recessions, in 2001 and 2008–9. is chapter proposes
establishing direct payments to individuals as an automatic stabilizer. e
lump-sum annual payments would be made to individuals, regardless of
their income level, when the national unemployment rate rises by at least
0.50 percentage points. e amount of the individual payments would be
set such that total payments equaled 0.7percent of GDP, or 1percent of
personal consumption expenditures (PCE). Payments in subsequent years
would be made only in the case of severe, prolonged recessions that lead
to cumulative unemployment rate increases of at least 2.0 percentage
points. Automatic stimulus payments to individuals would provide a rapid,
frontline defense early in a recession and a commitment to sustained
support in a severe recession.
Direct Stimulus Payments to
Individuals
Claudia Sahm, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
Claudia Sahm
68
Growth in consumer expenditures slows sharply during recessions—and
in many cases turns negative (gure 1). Consumer expenditures make up
about 70percent of aggregate demand; a pullback in spending by consumers
can lead to employment losses and reduced production. Consumers are
therefore a key focus of eorts to stabilize the economy, and policymakers
have oen used stimulus payments to individuals (also referred to as tax
rebates) and temporary reductions in taxes to support household spending
during recessions.
In fact, during the Great Recession and the recovery, individuals received
more than $420billion in broad-based stimulus from the federal government
through three large, consecutive policies: a stimulus payment in 2008, a tax
credit in 2009 and 2010 (the Making Work Pay tax credit), and a payroll
tax reduction in 2011 and 2012. ese programs were broad based in the
sense that they applied to many households with few qualications, such
as having a minimum amount of income. In each case, the administration
and Congress craed the specics of the stimulus program in real time,
along with other scal policies, including targeted discretionary changes in
taxes and transfers to support individuals, businesses, and state and local
governments. e range of stimulus programs in the Great Recession has
supported a rich body of research on the ecacy of various tools.
Automatic stabilizers are already an important feature of scal stabilization
policy, two of the most notable examples being progressive income taxation
#4a4a4a
#67c2a5
#d94343
#bd9f45
#5c7aa5
#776493
#f1e764
Website colors
Ocial logo
Dark
Reverse
Chart branding horizontal
Multimedia branding
Equitable
Growth
#f1f0f0 background
#006ba6
#f6511d
#711c77
#178c58
#b400
#CE0A1A
#5bc0be
Chart color palatte
FIGURE 1.
Real Personal Consumption Expenditures, 1970–2018
Source: Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA) 1969–2018; author’s
calculations.
Note: Shaded areas denote recessions.
-4
-2
0
2
4
6
8
10
1970 1974 1978 1982 1986 1990 1994 1998 2002 2006 2010 2014 2018
Four-quarter percent change
Direct Stimulus Payments to Individuals
69
and unemployment insurance (UI). Incomes tend to decline in recessions,
but given that marginal income tax rates are lower at lower income levels,
taxes fall more than income does. e disproportionate decline in income
tax burden helps to oset some of the loss in disposable income. e UI
system, by contrast, is a more narrowly targeted automatic stabilizer
that supports consumption for eligible workers who lose their jobs. In
a recession, as the unemployed rise in numbers so do payments from
UI. In both cases, these automatic stabilizers (and others including the
Supplemental Nutrition Assistance Program [SNAP], formerly the Food
Stamp Program) are oen paired with additional discretionary measures,
such as temporary tax cuts or temporary extensions of UI benets.
e choice between automatic and discretionary scal policy depends on
several factors. First, we want to do only what we know works, and the
evidence shows that direct, lump-sum payments are an eective scal tool.
Adding a new automatic stabilizer would be a commitment to increase
government support to households in a recession. Improved stabilization—
such as shortening the length or severity of a downturn—would limit the
economic costs of a recession. Even so, stabilizers are unlikely to pay for
themselves. Sucient scal space for such policies could require either
higher taxes or lower transfers outside of recessions. In this case, one could
view the budget for the automatic stimulus payments as a rainy-day fund
for payments to individuals that would be administered by the government.
e fund would accrue savings in good times and make payments in
bad times. Given the thin nancial buers of many households, the
direct stimulus payments would increase households’ resiliency during a
recession.
Making the stimulus payments to individuals fully automatic could have
some drawbacks. One concern is that it might give the incorrect appearance
that policymakers are inactive in the face of recession. One response
to this concern would be to implement the stimulus payments in two
legislative phases. First, legislation prior to a recession would determine
the features of prospective stimulus payments, such as size and targeting,
and would allow the preparation of administrative systems. en when
macroeconomic conditions warrant (according to a prespecied economic
trigger), Congress would vote on whether to enact the stimulus payments.
e precommitment to the form and delivery of payments would increase
the speed with which stimulus can be distributed but still allow Congress
to control the exact timing. e development of macroeconomic triggers
and schedules for additional payments would provide additional guidance
to policymakers, even if the implementation is not fully automatic.
Claudia Sahm
70
Policymakers would only want to make automatic the policies that have
proven to be cost eective in the past. In turn, the eectiveness of stimulus
payments in a recession largely depends on the spending response of
households. A temporary reduction in taxes or increase in transfers, if
either action boosts spending, can mitigate the job losses, underutilization
of productive resources, and widespread pessimism in recessions.
Nonetheless, simple economic models with forward-looking consumers
and well-functioning nancial markets tend to predict a small increase in
spending from a temporary boost to income. In fact, some models even
predict that individuals would save all of any rebate (yielding what is known
as Ricardian equivalence), under the assumption that people would have to
repay the debt-nanced stimulus with higher taxes in the future. Empirical
evidence (summarized below) across numerous research studies of the
Great Recession strongly suggests that at least some forms of stimulus to
households can measurably boost spending in the near term.
The Challenge
EVIDENCE ON THE EFFECTS OF DIRECT STIMULUS PAYMENTS PROVIDED
TO INDIVIDUALS
Mounting evidence in the past decade nds that broadly distributed
payments to individuals increase spending during a recession and help
stabilize the economy. is new research has overcome a methodological
challenge: previously, a challenge in showing the eectiveness of these
direct payments was the diculty in distinguishing the positive eects of
the direct payments from the negative eects of the recession. When these
stimulus payments are disbursed, the overall economy is weakening and so
the trajectory of total spending can make the stimulus look ineectual. In
other words, a simple comparison of consumer spending before and aer
a stimulus payment to individuals is not enough to determine whether
stimulus is eective.
A novel feature in the delivery of stimulus payments in 2001 and 2008
provided an opportunity to tease apart and separately identify the eect
of the payments. e resulting studies have bolstered the view that such
payments are an eective and fast-acting stimulus. Due to administrative
constraints on the number of payments that could be sent out at one time,
the timing of individuals’ payment in 2001 and 2008 was determined by
the last two digits of their Social Security number. is random variation
in the timing provided a way to measure spending before and aer a
stimulus payment under the same macroeconomic conditions. Comparing
the spending of individuals who have (randomly) already received their
payment with the spending of those who will (randomly) receive it in a
Direct Stimulus Payments to Individuals
71
BOX 1.
Stimulus Payments to Individuals During the Great
Recession
e mix of discretionary stimulus to individuals in the Great
Recession and subsequent research on the eects has provided
several lessons on the best ways to structure stimulus payments.
Early in the recession, the Economic Stimulus Act of 2008 enacted
on February 13, 2008, included one-time recovery rebates to
individuals. Most single tax lers received a $600 payment while
couples that were married and led jointly received $1,200 at some
point between May and July of 2008. Filers received an additional
$300 for each qualifying child. e rebates were phased out for
high-income earners, while individuals with nontaxable Social
Security or pension income were eligible for smaller lump-sum
payments.
Aer the nancial crisis and recession intensied in the second
half of 2008, a large array of scal stimulus policies was used. On
February 17, 2009, the Making Work Pay tax credit, a broad-based,
two-year tax cut for individuals, was signed into law as one part of
the expansive American Recovery and Reinvestment Act of 2009
(ARRA). e Making Work Pay tax credit was implemented via
lowering withholdings, so the annual tax savings of $400 for singles
and $800 for married couples was spread out in smaller amounts
across pay periods. As the Making Work Pay tax credit was set to
expire, a temporary 2-percentage-point cut in the payroll tax for
2011 was signed into law on December 17, 2010, in the Tax Relief,
Unemployment Insurance Reauthorization, and Job Creation Act
of 2010. A year later, on December 23, 2011, e Temporary Payroll
Tax Cut Continuation Act of 2011 extended the payroll tax cut for
the rst two months of 2012, and then on February 22, 2012, the
Middle Class Tax Relief and Job Creation Act of 2012 extended the
payroll tax cut through the end of 2012.
Notably, this last stimulus policy required three legislative actions,
underscoring how precommitment could simplify the process and
reduce uncertainty for households. As with the tax credits in 2009
and 2010, the reduction in payroll taxes was spread throughout the
year in the form of larger paychecks. One dierence is that this last
Claudia Sahm
72
matter of weeks helps to isolate the eect on spending of having (versus not
having) the stimulus payment.
Studies of the 2001 and 2008–9 recessions have yielded stimulus spending
estimates that are uniformly positive. Johnson, Parker, and Souleles (2006)
analyzed Consumer Expenditure Survey data in their study of the 2001
tax rebates. ey used the random variation in timing of payments to
estimate that, on average, households spent 20 to 40percent of their rebates
on nondurable goods in the three-month period when the rebate was
distributed. Within the rst six months, individuals spent nearly two thirds
of the rebate on nondurable goods. In their follow-up study of the 2008
rebate, Parker et al. (2013) estimate that 12 to 30percent of the rebate was
spent on nondurables within three months of receipt. Including durables
spending, 50 to 90percent of the rebate was spent over three months. With
the same data, Misra and Surico (2014) estimate that 40 to 50percent of the
households who received a payment in 2001 or 2008 did not change their
spending, but about 20percent spent half or more of their stimulus. Other
analyses using dierent data sources and randomized timing also nd
that the 2001 and 2008 tax rebates quickly boosted consumer spending.
Broda and Parker (2014) use transactions data in 2008 for a narrower set
of consumer goods and nd a 10percent increase in spending in the week
of receipt. Using credit card data, Agarwal, Liu, and Souleles (2007) nd
that initially the 2001 rebate led to a reduction in debt but then credit
card spending rose by about 40percent of the rebate amount within nine
months. Altogether, these studies nd a sizeable boost to spending from the
payments.
Aer making the case for sending income to many households in a recession,
the next challenge is structuring the payments to most eectively increase
demand. A key nding that draws on results in multiple research studies is
that larger one-time payments lead to more spending, more quickly, than
payments that are smaller or more spread out. e composition of spending
induced by the payments in 2001 and 2008 is one piece of the explanation.
Parker et al. (2013) nd that the larger payments in 2008 (almost twice the
size of the payments in 2001) led to a large increase in durable spending
stimulus was proportional to income (up to the taxable maximum),
whereas the earlier stimulus to individuals were closer to a lump-
sum payment. e temporary payroll tax cut was allowed to expire
at the end of 2012. Across these three stimulus programs more
than $420 billion in additional income was sent to individuals
from 2008 to 2012.
Direct Stimulus Payments to Individuals
73
within three months of receipt. In 2001 most of the spending response
came from nondurables and occurred over six months. Similarly, Misra
and Surico (2014) nd that some people increased their durable purchases
by more than the amount of their rebate, for example by using the stimulus
to make a down payment on a motor vehicle.
Another source of evidence in favor of large one-time payments comes
from a method developed by Shapiro and Slemrod (2003a, 2003b, 2009)
that asks individuals directly in surveys whether they planned to “mostly
spend,” “mostly save,” or “mostly pay o debt” with the stimulus. With the
one-time payments in 2001 and 2008, they found that about 20percent of
adults said that they had “mostly spent” the rebates.
1
When this method
was applied to the Making Work Pay tax credit in 200910, the spending
response was more muted. Sahm, Shapiro, and Slemrod (2012) nd that
the smaller, repeated boost to income from lower tax withholding led to
less additional spending than the one-time payments. e share of people
who planned to “mostly spend” the lower withholding from Making
Work Pay was about two-thirds the share who planned to spend the tax
rebate. e structure of the stimulus payments—not the deterioration in
macroeconomic conditions between the spring of 2008 and the spring of
2009—appears to have dampened the spending response. In both years
retirees received a small, lump-sum payment, and in both years their self-
reported spending rates were similar. In addition, among non-retirees
a hypothetical one-time payment elicited a spending rate higher than
the withholding change (similar to the eect observed for the 2008 tax
rebate). Similarly, Sahm, Shapiro, and Slemrod (2015) nd a similarly small
spending response to the payroll tax cut.
2
e evident lack of public awareness of the more gradual stimulus like
the Making Work Pay tax credit—as documented in Sahm, Shapiro, and
Slemrod (2012)—raises some additional questions. In particular, one role
of economic stabilization policy is to assuage the negative views on the
economy. Pessimism and uncertainty could lead households to pull back on
spending and instead save as a precaution. Durables spending, which can
be more easily delayed than nondurable necessities, is particularly sensitive
to precautionary savings motives. A stimulus payment—even disbursed
annually—is not large enough to make up for a job loss but it could temper
the need to build up extra savings as a precaution. Stimulus that is not
seen or recognized by individuals is unlikely to aect their sentiment and
tendency to engage in precautionary saving. e direct boost to spending
is the key criterion for ecacy of stimulus payments, but the saliency (or
sentiment) eects are also worth considering.
Claudia Sahm
74
RELEVANT EVIDENCE FROM OTHER CONSUMPTION RESEARCH
e nding that additional income boosts spending on receipt is conrmed
by other research, not specically related to stimulus payments or
discretionary tax cuts. Moreover, the initial spending response does not
appear to depend on the additional income being a surprise to households
(as has been the case with stimulus payments in the past). Simple, forward-
looking economic models predict an increase in spending only if the
temporary increase in income is unexpected. One concern with making
stimulus payments automatic is that they would be less of a surprise to
households than discretionary stimulus payments. Yet, research shows
that additional income will oen generate additional spending, even if
individuals anticipate the income and it is a regular, large payment, such as
the annual Alaska Fund payments (Kueng 2018) or the Earned Income Tax
Credit (Aladangady et al. 2018). Empirically, spending is tied to the receipt
of the income, a relationship that does not appear to dier much across
predictable and unpredictable income.
Research ndings are mixed on the benets of targeting stimulus to
low-income individuals. A common—but not universal—nding is that
households with low liquid assets relative to their income tend to spend
more (and more quickly) out of additional income than those households
with ample liquidity. us, as argued by Kaplan and Violante (2014),
even high-income households with illiquid assets, such as housing wealth
or retirement savings accounts, would spend out of stimulus income.
Targeting current low-income or low-wealth households may not identify
the households most likely to spend the stimulus, which could include
some wealthy households.
3
However, it would be dicult to target stimulus
payments to individuals with low liquidity, since the government does not
readily have information about households’ assets.
The Proposal
is section lays out the case for direct stimulus payments to individuals
to become part of our system of automatic stabilizers, building on the
evidence in the previous sections that additional income translates quickly
into additional spending. I discuss several economic considerations that
militate in favor of automatic stimulus payments. I then propose a specic
policy to deliver automatic scal stimulus through direct payments to
individuals.
ECONOMIC CONSIDERATIONS RELEVANT TO AUTOMATIC PAYMENTS
ere are three reasons why I argue that direct payments should be made
into an automatic stabilizer. First, automatic stimulus payments would
Direct Stimulus Payments to Individuals
75
provide a policy precommitment to broadly support aggregate demand in
a recession. Second, analysis and deliberation over the size, structure, and
funding of stimulus payments, as well as the development of administrative
procedures to disburse payments, could occur at a time other than the
crisis of a recession. Finally, automatic payments could also commit scal
policymakers to maintain support if the recession is severe and the recovery
is drawn out. e payroll tax cut, the last of the broad-based household
stimulus aer the Great Recession, expired in the rst quarter of 2013. At
that time, the national unemployment rate was still 2.7 percentage points
above its prerecession level—a sign that stimulus was withdrawn while the
economy was far from a full recovery.
4
Fiscal support during the Great
Recession was less than in prior recessions, and the additional stabilization
later in the recovery was largely due to monetary policy.
Putting administrative systems in place ahead of time could ensure that the
stimulus is delivered more quickly and more broadly. It is also important
to minimize errors and ensure that only intended populations receive the
payment. With the 2008 stimulus payments, the Internal Revenue Service
(IRS) estimated that it would require 60 days to program the system to
calculate payments aer the legislative details were settled (Joint Committee
on Taxation 2008). In addition, the payments could not be disbursed
during the peak tax ling system. us, without advance preparation of the
system, it is not currently possible to send out payments from late January
to mid-May each year.
Moreover, advance planning could also be used to reach a wider population
than those ling income tax returns. A key impediment to sending out
payments is the lack of a centralized, up-to-date address or electronic funds
transfer information on individuals. e IRS maintains this information for
tax lers, as does Social Security for all its benet recipients. Collaboration
between the IRS, the Social Security Administration, and other agencies
that interact with non-lers could also extend the receipt of payments to
more individuals than tax lers and ensure that individuals receive only a
single payment from the government.
Automatic stimulus payments in recessions and recoveries—paid for by
higher taxes during expansions—would provide additional liquidity when
uncertainty about employment and income is high. Many households
have low savings and even outside of recessions would have diculty
paying a modest unexpected expense (Board of Governors of the Federal
Reserve 2018). Given the thin nancial buers of many households and the
heightened uncertainty in a recession, automatic stimulus payments could
be a popular form of rainy-day savings and support to spending.
Claudia Sahm
76
Automatic stimulus payments to individuals would also be a broad-based,
transparent source of macroeconomic stabilization. Lump-sum payments
disbursed annually to households based on macroeconomic conditions
would be a more direct, easier-to-understand form of stimulus than changes
in interest rates or asset purchases via monetary policy. Income payments
would go directly to individuals and would not rely on propagation through
nancial and labor markets. Monetary policy is an eective way to stabilize
business cycles—lowering interest rates to increase demand during a
recession—but its initial direct eects vary across individuals (depending,
for example, on their assets and debts) and the overall, benecial eects
are oen hard to communicate.
5
e broad-based nature of the stimulus
payments would also make it easier to explain the details of the program to
the public, increasing its salience and eectiveness. Recessions coincide with
heightened pessimism and the stimulus payments would directly counter
that pessimism. Understanding how the government is directly supporting
individuals in the recession could create public support for more targeted
policies or for those policies with less direct eect on individuals.
POLICY PROPOSAL
I propose a new automatic stimulus payment—lump-sum annual payments
to individuals—that would be triggered automatically by a rise in the
unemployment rate. Key details of the proposal are as follows:
Automatic lump-sum stimulus payments would be made to individuals
when the three-month average national unemployment rate rises by
at least 0.50 percentage points relative to its low in the previous 12
months.
e total amount of stimulus payments in the rst year is set to
0.7percent of GDP.
Aer the rst year, any second (or subsequent) year payments would
depend on the path of the unemployment rate.
An increase of 2.0 percentage points or more from the initial
unemployment rate would result in a second year’s payments with
aggregate stimulus again equal to 0.7percent of GDP.
Aer the second year and aer the unemployment rate has peaked
(whichever comes later), the total stimulus amount would be scaled
down as the unemployment rate declines.
Annual payments would continue in the third (and subsequent)
years until the unemployment rate is no more than 2.0 percentage
points above the level at the time of the rst payment.
Direct Stimulus Payments to Individuals
77
Eligibility for direct stimulus payments would not be restricted to
households with taxable income.
All adults would receive the same base payment, and in addition,
parents of minor dependents would receive one half the base payment
per dependent.
Each aspect of the policy, including its administration, is discussed in more
detail below. is section concludes with an example of how the automatic
payments would have been applied in the Great Recession and recovery.
ese automatic stimulus payments to individuals should be thought of as a
rst line of defense in the recession and not a replacement for discretionary
scal policy or other automatic stabilizers, which could add to stimulus as
macroeconomic conditions evolve.
Trigger to Start Automatic Stimulus Payments
is proposal requires an explicit trigger that will turn on during a
cyclical downturn. is trigger could be used to automatically disburse the
payments or to initiate a congressional vote on payments. In this proposal,
the trigger is based on changes in the national unemployment rate.
e direct stimulus payments to individuals begin aer a 0.50 percentage
point increase or more in the three-month moving average of the
unemployment rate relative to its low in the prior 12 months (gure 2). e
three-month average smooths out some of the monthly random variation
in the rate and avoids false positives, such as stimulus payments made
outside economic downturns. e trigger depends on recent changes in the
unemployment rate, as opposed to a xed unemployment rate threshold,
because this type of trigger accommodates changes over time in the natural
rate of unemployment.
6
Even a modest rise in the unemployment rate such
as 0.50 percentage points (shown by the orange dashed line in gure 2) has
occurred only during or closely following recessions. In other words, by this
rule the stimulus payments would have been triggered only in recessions.
7
Based on past recessions (and the data available to policymakers at the
time), the change in the unemployment rate would be a highly eective
trigger for the stimulus payments. Early in each recession since 1970, the
unemployment rate rose at least a 0.50 percentage points (gure 3).
8
On
average, payments would have been triggered within three months of the
start of the past six recessions. e automatic trigger would have been met
four months aer the 20089 recession began and two months aer the
2001 recession began. e specic trigger in this proposal—comparing
the three-month average unemployment rate to its low over the prior 12
months—signals a recession well before the ocial dating of a recession.
Claudia Sahm
78
e proposed trigger would reliably deliver stimulus to the economy early
in recessions.
e unemployment rate has other advantages as the basis for the trigger
in an automatic stabilizer. e unemployment rate has been used as a core
signal of labor market strength and overall economic well-being, and has
been measured consistently for many decades. It is a timely measure: a
given months unemployment rate estimate is available at the beginning
of the subsequent month. By contrast, output growth is measured with a
lag, is revised frequently, and, given its volatility, would require waiting
for at least two to three weak quarters to signal recession. Partly due to
these advantages, the U.S. government has extensive experience using the
unemployment rate as a trigger for social programs. Making the stimulus
payments to individuals automatic once the unemployment rate trigger
is met would guarantee that stimulus ows to the economy quickly. If
administrative systems are already in place to disburse payments, then
individuals would receive their automatic payments early in the recession.
In contrast, for discretionary payments work also has to be done on both the
legislation and the logistics before stimulus can be delivered to households.
ere are some concerns with using the unemployment rate as a trigger
to start stimulus payments. First, the unemployment rate tends to lag the
business cycle, such that unemployment usually peaks aer the recession
has ended. e slow-moving nature of the unemployment rate implies
FIGURE 2.
Unemployment Rate (3-Month Average) Relative to Prior
12-Month Low, 19702018
Source: BLS 19692019; author’s calculations.
Note: Shaded areas denote recessions. Dashed orange line denotes
the proposed trigger threshold. Calculation uses real-time estimates
of the unemployment rate.
#4a4a4a
#67c2a5
#d94343
#bd9f45
#5c7aa5
#776493
#f1e764
Website colors
Ocial logo
Dark
Reverse
Chart branding horizontal
Multimedia branding
Equitable
Growth
#f1f0f0 background
#006ba6
#f6511d
#711c77
#178c58
#b400
#CE0A1A
#5bc0be
Chart color palatte
-0.5
0.0
0.5
1.0
1.5
2.0
2.5
3.0
3.5
4.0
4.5
1970 1974 1978 1982 1986 1990 1994 1998 2002 2006 2010 2014 2018
Percentage point dierence
Direct Stimulus Payments to Individuals
79
that it gives little advance warning of recessions. Still, as seen in gure 3,
this trigger would signal a downturn nearly immediately and long before
it has been ocially recognized. Second, the rise in unemployment prior
to a recession does not predict the severity of the recession. For example,
the increases in the unemployment rate prior to the 2001 and 2008–9
recessions were similar, even though the subsequent rise during and
aer the 2008–9 recession was more than double the rise with the 2001
recession. In other words, a prerecession unemployment rate rise is not a
good guide to the shortfall in demand in a recession and speaks to having
a plan for additional payments in severe recessions. Finally, one may worry
about whether people leaving the labor market or reentering it mask the
quality of the signal from the unemployment rate, but, at least at the start
of recessions, the change in the unemployment rate is a remarkably reliable
signal.
Aggregate Amount of Stimulus Payments
Because the goal of the direct payments to individuals is macroeconomic
stabilization and shallower recessions, the total amount of the stimulus is
a core concern. During the initial months of the recession when the rst
payment arrives, the eventual severity of the downturn will be unknown.
And, in fact, one goal of such fast-acting stimulus is to help stave o the
negative dynamics that oen accompany recessions—that is, the stimulus
can itself reduce the severity of the downturn. Fiscal stimulus can provide
FIGURE 3.
Date that Unemployment Rate Trigger Activated Relative to the
Start of Selected Recessions
Source: BLS 1969–2019; author’s calculations.
Note: Calculation uses real-time estimates of the unemployment
rate.
#4a4a4a
#67c2a5
#d94343
#bd9f45
#5c7aa5
#776493
#f1e764
Website colors
Ocial logo
Dark
Reverse
Chart branding horizontal
Multimedia branding
Equitable
Growth
#f1f0f0 background
#006ba6
#f6511d
#711c77
#178c58
#b400
#CE0A1A
#5bc0be
Chart color palatte
0
1
2
3
4
Mar 1974 Apr 1980 Nov 1981 Nov 1990 Jun 2001 Apr 2008
Month of trigger activation
Months since start of recession
Claudia Sahm
80
additional spending power to those who are liquidity constrained and
counteract the rise in precautionary savings that might otherwise lead to a
reduction in spending, particularly for purchases of durables that can more
easily be delayed.
I propose setting the total dollars of rst-year direct payments to address the
weakness in a typical recession. Since the mid-1970s, a typical recession has
entailed a slowdown in real consumer spending growth—on a four-quarter
basis—of about 2 percentage points, with substantially larger slowdowns
in growth in 1973 and 2008. In this proposal, direct payments that are half
of a typical recessions slowdown in consumer spending growth—equal to
approximately 1percent of real PCE (or about 0.7percent of GDP)—would
be a substantial commitment to stabilize the economy.
9
is additional
income, on aggregate, is on the high end of past discretionary payments.
By comparison the 2001 tax rebates were about 0.4percent of GDP, and
the payments in 2008 were about 0.7percent of GDP (Shapiro and Slemrod
2003b, 2009).
Several considerations speak in favor of a large initial stimulus to
households. First, the costs of recession, whether at the macroeconomic
level or at the household level, are substantial.
10
us, vigorous eorts to
stabilize demand early in a recession would have large payos. Second,
larger aggregate stimulus translates into larger individual payments. Large
direct payments to individuals are spent more quickly since their size can
support the purchase of (or the down payment on) large consumer durables,
such as automobiles (Parker et al. 2013). For consumers, large payments
are also more salient than small ones (Sahm, Shapiro, and Slemrod 2012),
allowing them to more eectively counter precautionary saving motives
and bolster popular support for stimulus. Finally, these direct stimulus
payments—especially if made automatically—would be some of the earliest
support to the economy in the recession. Most of the support from other
automatic stabilizers, including progressive income tax rates or UI benets,
arrive later than the initial months of a recession. Large, direct payments
to individuals would provide an aggressive, frontline defense against the
negative eects of a recession.
Structure and Targeting of Payments
With the aggregate amount of stimulus set, the next step is to structure the
individual payments to maximize the immediate boost to spending. From
the empirical research on the 2001 and 2008 to 2012 stimulus policies, the
propensity to spend out of the stimulus payments is likely to be highest
for one-time, lump-sum payments (Sahm, Shapiro, and Slemrod 2012). In
addition, one-time payments add stimulus spending more quickly to the
Direct Stimulus Payments to Individuals
81
economy than a change in tax withholding (which would spread scal
stimulus throughout the year). Consider two hypothetical $100 billion
stimulus packages. e rst is paid out in one-time payments (with all
individuals receiving checks within 10 weeks) and the second is spread out
evenly during the year in the form of higher take-home paychecks (via lower
tax withholding). Even if individuals responded to both forms of stimulus
in the same way—in other words, if the marginal propensity to consume
(MPC) out of each dollar was identical—it would not be until early in the
next year that the full stimulus spending occurred under the second option
(gure 4). e delay in payments necessarily delays individuals’ spending.
In contrast, the increase in spending from one-time payments would
occur within three months (Parker et al. 2013). Furthermore, because
research shows that the individual spending response is larger from one-
time payments than from changes in withholding (Sahm, Shapiro, and
Slemrod 2012), the overall stimulus boost would be both larger and more
rapid. e faster timing and higher spend rate favor one-time payments for
macroeconomic stabilization.
11
e speed—supported by empirical research—with which direct payments
increase aggregate demand is particularly important. To meet its primary
objective macroeconomic stabilization needs to occur when resources are
underutilized in the economy. e outright declines in output occur early
FIGURE 4.
Cumulative Spending by Disbursement Form and Spend Rate
Source: Author’s calculations.
Note: Spending is based on a $100 billion stimulus. The MPC, which
determines the spend rate, for lump sum payments is set at 0.7, with
60percent of the spending response in the rst month, 30percent
in the second month, and 10percent in the third month. The MPC for
withholding is alternately assumed to be 0.5 or 0.7.
#4a4a4a
#67c2a5
#d94343
#bd9f45
#5c7aa5
#776493
#f1e764
Website colors
Ocial logo
Dark
Reverse
Chart branding horizontal
Multimedia branding
Equitable
Growth
#f1f0f0 background
#006ba6
#f6511d
#711c77
#178c58
#b400
#CE0A1A
#5bc0be
Chart color palatte
Lump sum,
MPC = 0.7
Withholding,
MPC = 0.7
Withholding,
MPC = 0.5
0
25
50
75
100
3 months 6 months 9 months 12 months
Months since stimulus begins
Billions of dollars
Claudia Sahm
82
in recessions, and stimulus that quickly supports aggregate demand would
be particularly benecial. e direct spending out of stimulus payments
to individuals is followed by indirect (i.e., second-round or multiplier)
eects, in which production responds to the initial boost to spending.
ese multiplier eects are likely larger in a severe recession when more
slack exists in the economy (and even more so when monetary policy is
constrained at the zero lower bound). Stimulus demand, then, is less
likely to crowd out other spending (Auerbach and Gorodnichenko 2012).
is nding argues both for a rapid rst payment and for a commitment
to repeated payments in a severe recession until the lingering economic
weakness has subsided. Finally, as mentioned previously, other forms of
stabilization policy—for example, UI benets or reductions in interest rates
via monetary policy—tend to work with a lag, so stimulus payments oer
one of the most rapid responses in a recession. us, the direct payments to
individuals should be structured to maximize timeliness.
e direct stimulus payments to individuals would be made broadly
available and would not be restricted to those working or with tax
liabilities. e broad nature of the recipient pool aligns with the broad
negative economic eects of recessions. A dening feature of a recession is
the pullback in demand across a wide range of households: recessions lead
high- and low-income households alike to sharply reduce their assessments
of buying conditions (gure 5). Stimulus intended to boost demand in a
recession should therefore encompass a range of households.
12
Generally,
the fastest spending responses to additional income are from low-
liquidity individuals, but targeting liquidity is more dicult in existing
administrative data, and low liquidity also exists among higher-income
households.
However, some criteria are needed for eligibility for stimulus payments.
Individuals with any taxable or nontaxable income (like Social Security or
Veterans Aairs benets) would be eligible, though the stimulus payments
would not be tied directly to tax liability.
13
(Non-lers without any
income would also be eligible, though locating them can be a challenge.)
e presence of dependent children would increase the amount of the
stimulus payment. One important criterion would be that no individual
(or dependent) receives more than one payment in a round of stimulus
payments. Further limitations on eligibility, such as residency requirements
or no unpaid taxes, could be added to the legislation authorizing the
automatic stimulus payments.
Administration and Marketing of Stimulus Payments
e closest existing structure to the proposed stimulus has been the advance
payment of refundable, temporary tax credits. Given its experience with
Direct Stimulus Payments to Individuals
83
past discretionary stimulus payments and access to payment information
of lers, the IRS would be the appropriate agency to review and approve
disbursement of the stimulus payment. Making the payments automatic
and setting the structure in advance would allow for administrative systems
to be designed in advance. is would be especially important if the start
of the recession coincided with the annual processing of tax returns, when
administrative demands on the IRS are high.
An important administrative challenge in delivering broad-based
stimulus is that individuals without taxable income, such as many Social
Security beneciaries, would not normally le tax returns. Despite
multiple outreach eorts, Treasury estimates that only 59 percent of the
20million Social Security and Veterans Aairs benets recipients led a
stimulus-only return in 2008 and received a payment (U.S. Department
of the Treasury [Treasury] 2009). Another 24 percent were claimed as
dependents on other tax lings, but that le 17percent who were eligible
but did not receive the stimulus. Getting information—and instructions
on how to complete the forms—to eligible non-lers was one of the areas
where the IRS viewed its initial guidance as incomplete (Treasury 2008). A
commitment to cover these non-lers in future stimulus payments would
allow time for more coordination with Social Security, Veterans Aairs,
and other agencies delivering other benet payments. Social Security, for
example, has information to deliver payments, but only to those receiving
FIGURE 5.
Index of Consumer Purchasing Sentiment by Household Income
Quartile, 19802018
Source: Survey of Consumers, University of Michigan 1980–2018.
Note: Shaded areas denote recessions. Index for each income group
is the percent of consumers responding that they think it is a “good
time to buy major household items” minus the percent reporting it
is a bad time to buy, plus 100. Values above 100 indicate that more
consumers think it is a good time to buy durable goods. Series is a
four-quarter moving average.
#4a4a4a
#67c2a5
#d94343
#bd9f45
#5c7aa5
#776493
#f1e764
Website colors
Ocial logo
Dark
Reverse
Chart branding horizontal
Multimedia branding
Equitable
Growth
#f1f0f0 background
#006ba6
#f6511d
#711c77
#178c58
#b400
#CE0A1A
#5bc0be
Chart color palatte
60
80
100
120
140
160
180
200
1980 1983 1986 1989 1992 1995 1998 2001 2004 2007 2009 2012 2015 2018
Index
Bottom
quartile
Top quartile
Upper-middle
quartile
Lower-middle
quartile
Claudia Sahm
84
benets from Social Security. A centralized system for approving stimulus
payment recipients, overseen by the IRS, could use payment information
(mailing addresses or electronic funds transfer) from various agencies. e
coordination would expand the reach of the stimulus payments and still
avoid duplication of payments.
e marketing of the stimulus is another aspect of administering the
payments. e terms in which the stimulus is described are important.
Studies from psychology (Epley, Mak, and Idson 2006) have argued that
describing the additional income as a “tax rebate” yields a smaller spending
response than framing it as a “bonus.” Leigh (2012) found a larger response
to stimulus payments in Australia than in the United States during the
Great Recession and argued that the dierence may have been due to the
Australian government calling their payments “bonuses,” though of course
it is dicult to rule out other dierences between the two countries as the
determining factor.
Sending out information about the stimulus payments to recipients may also
be important. e U.S. Treasury sent letters to individuals about the 2008
stimulus payments prior to disbursement, but there were no information
campaigns to recipients of the subsequent Making Work Pay tax credit and
payroll tax cut. Awareness of the stimulus would highlight the government
support for individuals in the recession, but it is unclear how this aects
the spending response. Notably, none of the empirical studies of the earlier
stimulus payments found evidence of consumer spending responses prior
to the arrival of stimulus payments, either at the passage of the legislation
or at the receipt of informational mailings. Rather, the spending response
occurs at the time the income is received.
Stimulus Payments after the First Year of the Recession
Some recessions are more severe and prolonged than the typical recession,
and in such cases I propose additional rounds of direct payments to
individuals aer the rst year. e goal of these additional payments is
further macroeconomic stabilization and reduction of slack resources in
the economy as quickly as possible. A cumulative increase of 2 percentage
points or more in the unemployment rate in the four quarters aer the
initial trigger would result in a second round of payments. e aggregate
stimulus in the second year would be the same as in the initial year
(0.7 percent of prerecession GDP) and would follow the same payment
structure to individuals. Direct payments would continue each year until
the unemployment rate is no more than 2 percentage points above its initial
trigger level, though the total amount of the payments scales down aer the
unemployment rate has peaked. Specically, if the prerecession, the peak,
Direct Stimulus Payments to Individuals
85
and the current unemployment rates were 5, 10, and 9percent, respectively,
the total stimulus would be set at (9 – 5 – 2) / (10 – 5 – 2) = 2/3 of the rst-
year amount (or 2/3 of 0.7percent of GDP). When the unemployment rate
gap falls to less than 2 percentage points, stimulus is entirely discontinued.
Payments aer the rst year would be triggered in severe recessions: the
1973–75, 198182 and 2008–9 recessions are the only three recent examples
that would have met this criterion.
In each recession since the mid-1970s, the unemployment rate eventually
rose at least 2 percentage points during or immediately following the
recession, but with a sucient delay that it would not have qualied for
a second payment round under this proposal. One could argue that a
second payment to individuals would have been useful in these other
recessions. However, other more-targeted policies such as UI or SNAP
payments would better direct resources to those most in need. In addition,
discretionary scal policy could add further support, specic to the shocks
of that particular recession.
Simulation of Proposed Stimulus Payments in the Great Recession
e macroeconomic comparison of automatic stimulus payments to the
discretionary policies deployed in the Great Recession (see gure 6) serves
two purposes. One is to compare a quantitative example of automatic
stimulus payments with discretionary payments that have been used in the
past. e second is to be able to compare with other more-targeted automatic
stabilizers. Two advantages of automatic stimulus payments are the speed
and the scale with which they can deliver stimulus to the economy. Even if
this scal stabilization policy remains largely discretionary, these exercises
will help us understand and critically evaluate the menu of policy options
that are available to ght recessions.
In April 2008 the (three-month average) unemployment rate was 5.0percent,
up 0.50 percentage points from its low in April 2007. Under the proposal,
this rise would have automatically triggered a direct stimulus payment to
individuals. e disbursement of the direct payments would have begun
within a few months aer the trigger was reached. In this case, the rst
stimulus payments would have been disbursed in the second quarter of
2008, somewhat sooner than were the tax rebates in 2008. Total stimulus
payments of $100 billion—equivalent to 0.7 percent of GDP in 2006
would have been issued. e automatic payments in 2008 would have been
around $500 for singles or $1,000 for couples, with higher payments for
those with dependent children.
e main dierence between the actual stimulus to individuals (from the
2008 tax rebates, Making Work Pay tax credit, and payroll tax reduction)
Claudia Sahm
86
and the proposed direct payments would have arisen aer the rst year.
In April 2009, the unemployment rate (on three-month average basis) was
8.5 percenta 12 month increase of 3.5 percentage points from its level
at the time of the rst trigger—and was still rising. is rapid, rst-year
increase (above the 2-percentage-point threshold) in the unemployment
rate would signal a severe recession and would have triggered an additional
round of direct stimulus payments to individuals. e second round of
direct payments to individuals in 2009 would have again been $100billion,
larger and more quickly distributed than the $50 billion in additional
income from the Making Work Pay tax credit. Subsequent annual payments
would continue at that level until the unemployment rate had peaked and
was no longer rising relative to its level at the prior year’s payment. At that
point, the annual payments would scale down as the unemployment rate
declines and end when the unemployment rate is within 2 percentage points
of its initial trigger. e total amounts of the direct payments in gure 6 are
only a rough approximation to show the trajectory and timing, and do not
take into account how the direct payments might aect the unemployment
rate. e purpose of the larger, more-rapid stimulus payments is to make
the recession shallower and the recovery faster. In fact, under the proposal
(and the assumptions above about MPCs) the boost to spending in 2008
and 2009 together would have been about one and a half times larger than
under actual policy.
Repeated, large direct payments to individuals oers three main benets
relative to the discretionary policy mix of broad-based stimulus to
FIGURE 6.
Automatic Proposal Versus Discretionary Stimulus Income in the
Great Recession, 2008–13
Source: BLS 2008–13; BEA 2009; BEA 2015; author’s calculations.
#4a4a4a
#67c2a5
#d94343
#bd9f45
#5c7aa5
#776493
#f1e764
Website colors
Ocial logo
Dark
Reverse
Chart branding horizontal
Multimedia branding
Equitable
Growth
#f1f0f0 background
#006ba6
#f6511d
#711c77
#178c58
#b400
#CE0A1A
#5bc0be
Chart color palatte
policy (left)
5
6
7
8
9
10
11
0
20
40
60
80
100
120
2008:Q1 2009:Q1 2010:Q1 2011:Q1 2012:Q1 2013:Q1
Proposal (left)
Actual policy
(left)
Unemployment rate
(right)
Billions of dollars
Percent
Direct Stimulus Payments to Individuals
87
individuals that was used in the Great Recession. First, the proposed stimulus
payments are more concentrated in the initial years of the recession when
the unemployment rate and slack in the economy was highest. Second, the
proposal commits to maintaining stimulus while the unemployment rate
remains elevated. In contrast, during the Great Recession the payroll tax
cut expired when the unemployment rate was nearly 8percent. ird, the
relevant research indicates that the proposals lump-sum annual payments
are expected to have an MPC of 0.7 within a quarter or two of receipt, one
third higher than the MPC of 0.5 on the smoothed stimulus (distributed
via lower withholding) that was used during the Great Recession. Taken
together, this proposal for direct payments to individuals is designed to
deliver timely, substantial, and ongoing support to the economy in the
event of a severe recession.
Ongoing Research Evaluation
To further study the macroeconomic eects of scal stimulus, the proposal
establishes a process for rigorous evaluation of the eects on spending.
Fortuitously, administrative constraints on the number of paper checks that
the federal government could send out in week led to a natural experiment
during the past two recessions. e timing of stimulus payments in 2001
and 2008 were randomized by Social Security numbers. In conjunction
with the addition of information to ocial consumer surveys, this allowed
researchers to credibly demonstrate the ecacy of stimulus payments.
With the rise in electronic funds transfers, the constraint on the volume
of payments that can be processed at once has been relaxed. Even so, for
evaluation purposes it would be benecial to maintain some randomization
in the timing of payments. Social Security numbers remain an option,
though this information is not regularly collected in ocial household
surveys, and the data on spending would be available only with a substantial
delay. Account level data, such as from nancial apps or bank account data
sources, might be another option for tracking incoming payments and the
spending response, but a nontrivial portion of the population does not
have such accounts. Another option for randomization in disbursement
would be physical location, such as timing based on the nal digit of a zip
code. Geographic variation in the stimulus payments would widen the
set of evaluation data sources and could be used to explore dierences in
underlying macroeconomic conditions that aect the spending responses
to the stimulus. e main policy goal is to deliver stimulus quickly to
households, but given the large commitment of resources some design
features should be studied to inform the design of future policies.
Claudia Sahm
88
Questions and Concerns
1. Are there other macroeconomic indicators that could be used as triggers for the
stimulus payments?
e unemployment rate has the benets of being simple to explain and
widely followed. Indicators from the nancial market, such as the yield
curve or near-term forward spread (Engstrom and Sharpe 2018), are also
potential predictors of recessions. However, nancial market indicators
tend to produce more false positives (in part due to monetary policy
responses).
2. How would the Congressional Budget Oce score an automatic stimulus
payment?
If the proposal was enacted during an expansion, precommitting to
stimulus payments in the event of a recession would necessitate the use of
probabilistic scoring by the Congressional Budget Oce (CBO), according
to which the CBO would project the expected value of the payments over
a ten-year window. In contrast, a two-stage implementation in which the
payments must be authorized by Congress would be scored according to
the full cost of the payments, given that the recession would already have
started. Consequently, the estimated cost would likely be lower outside a
recession, but at the time the pressing need for the outlay would be lower,
too.
3. Would the payments have to be annual or could multiple payments occur
during the year?
e baseline proposal is for annual payments, but once the infrastructure of
distributing payments is in place, it could be used at any time. Accelerating
the schedule of payments based on changes in economic conditions via
additional legislation would be another way to reintroduce legislative
control. For example, the case could have been made for a second stimulus
payment at the end of 2008 aer the severe disruption in nancial markets.
4. Would a smaller, more geographically targeted stimulus be preferable?
One option to limit the overall costs and to still support demand would be
to target payments aer the rst year to parts of the country in which the
unemployment rate has risen most. For example, the 2-percentage-point
threshold applied nationally in the baseline proposal for a second round
could instead be applied at the state level. is would allow the stimulus to
take into account both national and local economic conditions. However,
this geographic targeting would move away from the principle of broad-
based income and consumption support. Other policies, such as federal
grants to states and localities, would likely be a more eective way to
Direct Stimulus Payments to Individuals
89
geographically target stimulus. e baseline automatic stimulus payments
could provide broad national support and then be combined with the other
discretionary, geographically targeted policies.
Conclusion
Direct stimulus payments would quickly deliver extra income to millions
of households at the start of a recession and maintain income support until
the recession has subsided. High-quality research on similar payments
in the past shows that this form of stimulus directly boosts spending and
helps stabilize demand. Making the payments automatic and tying them to
changes in the national unemployment rate would guarantee a timely and
transparent source of demand in recessions. e individual payments in
the proposal are designed—based on available research—to maximize the
spending out of the stimulus and thereby increase the ecacy of the scal
stimulus. As part of a broad portfolio of automatic stabilization policies,
the proposal can help mitigate the worst costs of economic downturns.
Acknowledgments
e views expressed here are those of the author and not necessarily those
of other members of the Federal Reserve System. I am grateful for many
insightful comments and encouragement from the project editors, Heather
Boushey, Ryan Nunn, and Jay Shambaugh, as well as from participants in a
Hamilton Project author’s conference. Jana Parsons and Jimmy O’Donnell
provided excellent research assistance. is work draws on several years of
research collaboration with Matthew Shapiro and Joel Slemrod.
Endnotes
1. ese survey responses on stimulus do not map directly to a fraction of the payment spent, but
Parker and Souleles (forthcoming) nd a strong, positive correlation between spending behavior
and self-assessments in the Consumer Expenditure Survey.
2. With another survey, Graziani, van der Klaauw, and Zafar (2016) found that the self-reported
fraction spent out of the payroll tax cut rose from 14percent in early 2011 to 36percent at the end
of 2011. e spending out of this gradual stimulus may slowly rise over time, but the boost is still
less immediate than the boost from one-time payments.
3. e evidence (and interpretation) of the role of liquidity in spending responses varies to some
extent across empirical studies. For example, Parker (2017) nds that low liquidity in years prior
to receiving the tax rebate predicts a spending response nearly as well as low liquidity at the time
of receipt. is nding could suggest dierences in preferences and relates to earlier work such as
the Campbell-Mankiw spender-saver model and research from Carroll et al. (2017) on patience
that appeals to individual-specic preferences for spending. In addition, Kueng (2018) nds a large
spending response to payments among high-income households with ample liquid assets.
4. Compared to past business cycles and including estimates of discretionary scal policy and
automatic stabilizers, Cashin et al. (2018) nd that the scal support during the Great Recession
Claudia Sahm
90
was substantial but the support in the recovery was less than in earlier recessions.
5. As one example of the diculty in communicating the benets of monetary policy: Savers who
hold interest-bearing assets will initially receive less interest income due to expansionary monetary
policy; however, these policies to boost aggregate demand and stabilize the economy will lead to
higher interest rates in the future. On net, savers benet from monetary policy, but this is not as
transparent as receiving a direct payment.
6. e unemployment rate consistent with minimal labor market slack—sometimes called the natural
rate of unemployment—may change as demographics, labor market frictions, and other variables
evolve over time (see, e.g., estimates from the Congressional Budget Oce [CBO 2019] that range
from a high of 6.2percent in 1978 in to a low of 4.6percent in 2019).
7. Earlier in the postwar period (not shown in gure 2) the only false positive by this rule was in 1959,
and it was followed six months later by a recession.
8. roughout, I use the data on the unemployment rate available to policymakers at a given moment
in time. In general, the real-time data trigger a few months later than would the fully revised data.
9. Measured growth in GDP (or PCE) reects the eect of past scal and monetary stimulus. e
typical shortfall in aggregate demand in a recession—in the absence of stimulus—would be larger.
An estimate of that counterfactual time series could be a better way to calibrate the size of the total
stimulus. e estimates of scal policy eects in Cashin et al. (2018) could be used to calibrate the
underlying GDP changes.
10. As one recent example of the individual eects, Davis and von Wachter (2011) estimate that
workers who are laid o when the unemployment rate is above 8percent lose 2.8 years of potential
earnings, twice the loss when the unemployment rate is below 6 percent. For the economy as a
whole, Reifschneider, Wascher, and Wilcox (2013) argue that weak demand in severe recessions
like the Great Recession can lead to slower growth in the economy’s overall productive capacity (or
aggregate supply). Large, long-lasting costs from recessions are why it is important to stabilize the
economy as quickly as possible.
11. Other policy goals, such as increasing take-home pay or making taxes more progressive, could favor
withholding changes over one-time payments. e argument here for one-time payments is based
on trying to bring additional support to the economy during a recession and time of weak aggregate
demand. One-time payments could also be combined with broader changes in the tax code.
12. Other automatic stabilizers such as UI or SNAP are targeted to those who are most severely aected
by the recession. is proposal has a broader aim. Moreover, decoupling the stimulus payments
from an individual’s tax liability simplies the structure of the payments and allows for anchoring
on the overall stimulus level desired.
13. While retirees are not exposed to the risk of losing their jobs or reduced wage growth, those living
on xed incomes are oen aected by the low interest rates in recessions.
References
Agarwal, Sumit, Chunlin Liu, and Nicholas Souleles. 2007. “e Reaction of Consumer Spending
and Debt to Tax Rebates—Evidence from Consumer Credit Data.” Journal of Political Economy
115 (6): 986–1019.
Aladangady, Aditya, Shifrah Aron-Dine, David Cashin, Wendy Dunn, Laura Feiveson, Paul
Lengermann, Katherine Richard, and Claudia Sahm. 2018. “High-frequency Spending
Responses to the Earned Income Tax Credit.” FEDS Notes. Board of Governors of the Federal
Reserve, Washington, DC.
American Recovery and Reinvestment Act of 2009 (ARRA) Pub. L. 111–5 (2009).
Auerbach, Alan J., and Yuriy Gorodnichenko. 2012. “Measuring the Output Responses to Fiscal
Policy.” American Economic Journal: Economic Policy 4 (2): 1–27.
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve. 2018. Report on the Economic Well-Being of U.S.
Households in 2017. Washington, DC.
Direct Stimulus Payments to Individuals
91
Broda, Christian, and Jonathan A. Parker. 2014. “e Economic Stimulus Payments of 2008 and the
Aggregate Demand for Consumption.” Journal of Monetary Economics 68: 20–36.
Bureau of Economic Analysis. 1969–2018. “Table 1.1.6. Real Gross Domestic Product, Chained
Dollars: Personal Consumption Expenditures.” Last revised on December 21, 2018. U.S.
Department of Commerce, Suitland, MD.
———. 2009. “Government Receipts and Expenditures: ird Quarter of 2009.Survey of Current
Business 89 (12): 1114.
———. 2015. “Federal Recovery Programs and BEA Statistics: Tax Provisions.” Last updated August
27, 2015. U.S. Department of Commerce, Suitland, MD.
Bureau of Labor Statistics. 1969–2019. “Civilian Unemployment Rate.” Bureau of Labor Statistics,
Washington DC. Retrieved from ALFRED, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, St. Louis, MO.
Carroll, Christopher, Jiri Slacalek, Kiichi Tokuoka, and Matthew N. White. 2017. “e Distribution
of Wealth and the Marginal Propensity to Consume.Quantitative Economics 8: 9771020.
Cashin, David, Jamie Lenney, Byron Lutz, and William Peterman. 2018. “Fiscal Policy and
Aggregate Demand in the USA Before, During, and Following the Great Recession.”
International Tax and Public Finance 25 (6): 1519–58.
Congressional Budget Oce (CBO). 2019. “An Update to the Budget and Economic Outlook: 2019 to
2029.” Congressional Budget Oce, Washington, DC.
Davis, Steven J. and Till von Wachter. 2011. “Recessions and the Costs of Job Loss.” Brookings Papers
on Economic Activity, 2011 (2): 1–72.
Economic Stimulus Act, Pub.L. 110185, 122 Stat. 613 (2008).
Engstrom, Eric, and Steve Sharpe. 2018. “e Near-Term Forward Yield Spread as a Leading
Indicator: A Less Distorted Mirror.” Finance and Economics Discussion Series No. 2018-055,
Federal Reserve Board, Washington, D.C.
Epley, Nicholas, Dennis Mak, and Lorraine Chen Idson. 2006. “Bonus of Rebate?: e Impact of
Income Framing on Spending and Saving.Journal of Behavioral Decision Making 19 (3):
21327.
Graziani, Grant, Wilbert van der Klaauw, and Basit Zafar. 2016. “Workers’ Spending Response to the
2011 Payroll Tax Cuts.” American Economic Journal: Economic Policy 8 (4): 124–59.
Johnson, David, Jonathan A. Parker, and Nicholas S. Souleles. 2006. “Household Expenditure and
the Income Tax Rebates of 2001.American Economic Review 95 (5): 1589–610.
Joint Committee on Taxation. 2008. “Overview of Past Tax Legislation Providing Fiscal Stimulus
and Issues in Designing and Delivering a Cash Rebate to Individuals.” U.S. Congress Joint
Committee on Taxation, Washington, DC.
Kaplan, Greg, and Giovanni L. Violante. 2014. “A Model of the Consumption Response to Fiscal
Stimulus Payments.Econometrica 82 (4): 1199–239.
Kueng, Lorenz. 2018. “Excess Sensitivity of High-Income Consumers.” e Quarterly Journal of
Economics 133 (4): 16931751.
Leigh, Andrew. 2012. “How Much Did the 2009 Australian Fiscal Stimulus Boost Demand? Evidence
from Household-Reported Spending Eects.” e B.E. Journal of Macroeconomics. 12 (1):
1935–1960.
Middle Class Tax Relief and Job Creation Act of 2012 Pub.L. 112–96, H.R. 3630, 126 Stat. 156 (2012).
Misra, Kanishka, and Paolo Surico. 2014. “Consumption, Income Changes, and Heterogeneity:
Evidence from Two Fiscal Stimulus Programs.American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics
6 (4): 84–106.
Parker, Jonathan A. 2017. “Why Don’t Households Smooth Consumption? Evidence from a $25
Million Experiment.” American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 9 (4): 153–83.
Parker, Jonathan A., and Nicholas S. Souleles. Forthcoming. “Reported Eects vs. Revealed
Preference Estimates: Evidence from the Propensity to Spend Tax Rebates.” American
Economic Review: Insights.
Parker, Jonathan A., Nicholas S. Souleles, David S. Johnson, and Robert McClelland. 2013.
“Consumer Spending and the Economic Stimulus Payments of 2008.American Economic
Review 103 (6): 2530–53.
Claudia Sahm
92
Reifschneider, David, William L. Wascher, and David W. Wilcox. 2013. “Aggregate Supply in the
United States: Recent Developments and Implications for the Conduct of Monetary Policy.”
Federal Reserve Board Finance and Economics Discussion Series No. 2013-77.
Sahm, Claudia R., Matthew D. Shapiro, and Joel Slemrod. 2012. “Check in the Mail Or More in the
Paycheck: Does the Eectiveness of Fiscal Stimulus Depend on how it is Delivered?” American
Economic Journal: Economic Policy 4 (3): 216–50.
———. 2015. “Balance-Sheet Households and Fiscal Stimulus: Lessons from the Payroll Tax Cut and
Its Expiration.Finance and Economics Discussion Series No. 2015-037.
Shapiro, Matthew D. and Joel Slemrod. 2003a. “Consumer Response to Tax Rebates.” American
Economic Review 93(1): 381–96.
———. 2003b. “Did the 2001 Tax Rebate Stimulate Spending? Evidence from Taxpayer Surveys.”In
Tax Policy and the Economy, vol. 17, edited by James Poterba 83–109.Cambridge, MA:MIT
Press.
———. 2009. “Did the 2008 Tax Rebates Stimulate Spending?” American Economic Review Papers
and Proceedings 99: 3749.
Tax Relief, Unemployment Insurance Reauthorization, and Job Creation Act of 2010, Pub.L. 111-312
(2010).
Temporary Payroll Tax Cut Continuation Act, H.R. 3765 (2011).
University of Michigan. 1980–2018. “Survey of Consumers.” University of Michigan, Ann Arbor,
MI.
U.S. Department of the Treasury (Treasury). 2008. “Evaluation of Planning Eorts for the Issuance
of Economic Stimulus Payments” Treasury Inspector General for Administration, U.S.
Department of the Treasury, Washington, DC.
———. 2009. “Evaluation of Eorts to Ensure Eligible Individuals Received eir Economic
Stimulus Payment” Treasury Inspector General for Administration, U.S. Department of the
Treasury, Washington, DC.