Sub-national Revenue
Mobilization in Mexico
Luis César Castañeda
Juan E. Pardinas
Department o
f
Research and Chie
f
Economist
IDB-WP-354
IDB WORKING PAPER SERIES No.
Inter-American Development Bank
November 2012
Sub-nat
i
onal Revenue Mob
i
l
i
zat
i
on
in Mexico
Luis C
é
sar Castañeda
Juan E. Pardinas
Instituto Mexicano para la Competitividad, A.C.
2012
Inter-American Development Bank
http://www.iadb.org
The opinions expressed in this publication are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the
views of the Inter-American Development Bank, its Board of Directors, or the countries they
represent.
The unauthorized commercial use of Bank documents is prohibited and may be punishable under the
Bank's policies and/or applicable laws.
Copyright © Inter-American Development Bank. This working paper may be reproduced for
any non-commercial purpose. It may also be reproduced in any academic journal indexed by the
American Economic Association's EconLit, with previous consent by the Inter-American Development
Bank (IDB), provided that the IDB is credited and that the author(s) receive no income from the
publication.
Cataloging-in-Publication data provided by the
Inter-American Development Bank
Felipe Herrera Library
Castañeda, Luis César.
Sub-national revenue mobilization in Mexico / Luis César Castañeda, Juan E. Pardinas.
p. cm. (IDB working paper series ; 354)
Includes bibliographical references.
1. Revenue—Mexico. 2. Taxation—Mexico. 3. Finance, Public—Mexico. I. Pardinas, Juan E. II. Inter-
American Development Bank. Research Dept. III. Title. IV. Series. IDB-WP-354
2012
1
Abstract
This paper estimates potential Mexican sub-national tax revenues using a
stochastic frontier model. The results suggest that states are exploiting their
current tax bases, particularly the payroll tax, appropriately. Mexican
municipalities, however, have a low rate of tax collection compared to their
potential, especially in relation to the property tax, which is their most important
source of revenue and relatively simple to collect. Empirical evidence further
suggests that tax collection efforts are strongly related to GDP per capita, and that
some political economy factors can influence them. Political affiliation, for
example, influences municipalities’ tax collection effort more than that of states.
The analysis of a scenario in which some VAT and PIT taxation powers are
returned to the states suggests that a state surcharge on the VAT and PIT could
increase states’ own revenues. Without broadening the tax base and redefining the
revenue-sharing allocation criteria, however, doing so would have a strong and
adverse impact on the revenue distribution of sub-national governments.
JEL Classification: H3, H7, H71
Key words: Sub-national revenue, Value-added tax, Income tax, State and
municipal tax collection, Mexico
2
1. Introduction
In the near future, Mexico will face one of the biggest fiscal challenges in its history: the need to
diversify its tax revenue in order to decrease its high dependence on oil revenues. Oil revenues
have financed the current level of public expenditures (including investments), which cannot be
sustained without this source of financing. The high degree of uncertainty, oil price volatility,
and ongoing depletion of oil reserves point to the urgency of finding alternative sources of
revenue. Mexico is among the countries with the lowest tax revenue in proportion to GDP.
Including oil revenues, Mexico collects only 17.4 percent of GDP. Moreover, excluding this
non-renewable source, tax collection is about 10.3 percent, while the OECD average is 33.8
percent. Countries such as Denmark and Sweden collect more than 45 percent of their GDP,
while a country like Poland, which has a GDP per capita more similar to Mexicoscollects
31.8 percent. Mexican revenue is low even when compared with other Latin American countries;
Brazil collects 33.1 percent and Argentina 31.5 percent.
1
This paper explores alternative methods for increasing tax revenue in Mexico. In
particular, it focuses on the potential of sub-national units given the low degree of fiscal
autonomy among them. In 2007, only 4 percent of total general government revenues were
collected by states and municipalities. Among OECD countries, where sub-national revenues
average about 22.6 percent of total revenues, only Ireland and Greece have lower shares of sub-
national revenues (Figure 1). For some federal countries, such as Switzerland and Canada, the
figure is close to 50 percent. The legal framework of the Mexican Fiscal Coordination Law
published in 1997 has largely contributed to the increase in expenditure authority of states and
municipalities without promoting tax collection responsibilities. This situation leaves local and
Federal governments in a vulnerable position given the high dependency of oil prices. Some also
argue that this disconnection between expenditure and collection increases the chances of
mismanagement of public monies and diminishes the quality of government (Huntington 1991:
65).
1
OECD Revenue Statistics 2009 and CEPAL.http://websie.eclac.cl/sisgen/ConsultaIntegradaFlashProc.asp
3
Figure 1. Sub-national Revenue as a Percent of Total Revenue, 2007
Source: OECD revenue statistics.
This paper uses a stochastic frontier analysis to determine the tax collection effort of
states and municipalities in Mexico. This technique allows an estimation of the potential tax
collection of fiscal units given certain characteristics. Tax collection effort is defined here as the
ratio of observed tax collection to the potential collection at the efficiency frontier. The analysis
shows that most states and municipalities underperform in tax collection effort given their
economic and political characteristics, current fiscal authorities, and tax bases. However, even if
states and municipalities were to exploit their total potential, states’ total revenue would increase
only by 6 percent, compared to 23 percent for the municipalities
These results suggest that state tax bases are relatively well-exploited, which suggests
that the current tax system should be reformed in order to increase states’ revenue. Scenarios of
reforms for consumption, personal income and electricity taxes are shown here as various
options for increasing fiscal revenue of Mexican states.
0
5
10
15
20
25
30
35
40
45
50
Greece
Ireland
Mexico
Luxemborug
UK
New Zealand
Portugal
Turkey
France
Norway
Italy
Australia
Austria
Belgium
Finland
Demnark
Iceland
Japan
Spain
Germany
Sweeden
USA
Switzerland
Canada
4
2. The Mexican Fiscal Challenge in Light of the Decline in Oil Production
In recent decades, Mexican public finances have been characterized by high dependence on the
oil industry. As of December 2010, Mexico received one third of its total budgeted revenues
from the oil industry. Twenty years ago, the situation was exactly the same. In 1990, the oil
industry contributed 30 percent of the nation’s total budgeted revenues.
2
Hence, Mexico has
failed to reduce its vulnerability to the very volatile price of a single commodity. Furthermore,
diversification of revenue sources has not been achieved despite diminished oil production
capacity.
On the expenditure side, the enforcement in 1997 of a new Fiscal Coordination Law
centralized most revenue-raising responsibilities in the federal government, while decentralizing
a large portion of national expenditure to sub-national governments. In 1990, states and
municipalities together spent 20 percent of the nation’s total budget. Currently, their share of
general government (GG) spending is 57 percent. The states control the largest part (46 percent)
of this spending. Since 1990, states have gone from raising 32 percent of their total resources to
generating only 8 percent on average. The amount of resources raised locally by municipalities
has declined from 33 percent to 19 percent on average.
3
Figure 2 illustrates the drastic loss of sub-national fiscal autonomy, while Figure 3
illustrates the increase in their share of the expenditures. As can be inferred from both figures,
sub-national governments, and states in particular, have gained substantially greater expenditure
authority without acquiring further revenue-generating responsibilities. The heavy dependence
of the states on federal transfers has turned the federal government into their lender of last resort,
with the attendant moral hazard and risks for the federal budget.
2
SHCP. Estadísticas Oportunas de Finanzas Públicas y Deuda Pública. México, 2010.
3
IMCO. Índice de Competitividad Urbana 2010: Acciones urgentes para las ciudades del futuro. México, 2010.
5
Figure 2. State Revenues Raised by the Federal Government, 1989-2008
(as percent of total)
Source: IMCO with data from INEGI.
Figure 3. Distribution of General Government Expenditures, 1989-2007
(as percent of total)
Source: IMCO with data from INEGI.
Only four out of 32 state governments in Mexico finance more than 10 percent of their
expenditures (a low margin in itself) through own revenues. Table 1 ranks the 31 states plus the
Federal District by their degree of fiscal autonomy (defined as local taxes, rights, royalties, and
other local fees as a percentage of their total revenues).
6
Table 1. Sub-national Fiscal Autonomy, 2009
(own revenues as percent of total revenues)
33.0%
Distrito Federal
19.2%
Chihuahua
15.2%
Nuevo León
14.3%
Baja California Sur
9.4%
Guanajuato
8.5%
Baja California
7.7%
Campeche
7.4%
Sinaloa
6.9%
Hidalgo
6.9%
México
6.7%
Jalisco
6.3%
Tamaulipas
6.0%
Veracruz
5.8%
Chiapas
5.5%
Durango
5.5%
Aguascalientes
5.4%
San Luis Potosí
5.3%
Colima
4.9%
Yucatán
4.7%
Michoacán
4.3%
Puebla
3.9%
Morelos
3.5%
Guerrero
3.5%
Nayarit
3.4%
Tabasco
3.1%
Oaxaca
2.6%
Tlaxcala
Source: IMCO with data from the states’ budget laws.
If we consider that the federal government finances 92 percent of the state
governments’ budgets, and that 33 percent of federal revenues come from the oil industry
while sub-national governments have little say on oil policies, the following question
arises: how does oil dependence affect state governments? Using a straightforward
calculation with the mathematical formulas from the Fiscal Coordination Law, and holding
constant other variables,
4
a decrease in the price of a barrel of oil by US$2.00 should
represent an average decrease of 0.74 percent in State revenues through federal transfers.
However, given the requirement that federal transfers should be at least equivalent to the
amount calculated the prior year, this reduction is entirely absorbed by the Federal
government through spending cutoffs or increases in its debt, rather than passed on to the
subnational governments.
Although, municipalities have significantly greater fiscal autonomy than states, as
can be seen in Figure 4, the capacity of the third level of government to raise its own
resources has also declined over time, and has been replaced by federal transfers. In 1989,
4
Daily oil barrel production, estimated annual oil barrel price, oil barrel exportation, USD-MXN exchange
rate, revenue from the income tax, revenue from the value added tax, and revenue from the business tax.
7
municipalities raised 39 percent of their own revenues. By 2009, this had declined to an
average of 19 percent, as they came to depend increasingly on federal or state transfers,
which increased their vulnerability to unpredictable fluctuations in the oil market.
Figure 4. Federal and State Transfers to Municipalities, 1989-2009
as a Percent of Total Revenue
Source: IMCO with data from INEGI.
Mexico’s Fiscal Coordination Law and its political structure make it virtually
impossible to precisely identify the amount of oil revenues that are transferred to
municipalities. The Fiscal Coordination Law allows each state to determine the mechanism
for the distribution of federal transfers to its municipalities. Until 2010, for example, the
state of Chihuahua lacked a formula for calculating such transfers. Instead, the amount to
be transferred to each municipality was determined by a legislative decree. However, even
if municipalities could be subject to some degree of uncertainty regarding their share of oil
revenues, they are still protected by the restrictions stipulated in the Fiscal Coordination
Law.
The Fiscal Coordination Law establishes that federal transfers to sub-national
governments, regulated by a formula, cannot be reduced. Furthermore, the Fiscal
Coordination Law dictates that federal transfers to states be at least the same as the amount
calculated the prior year. The only reasons that federal transfers can decrease are: i) a fiscal
crisis wherein the national income is less than the year before, in which case the state
40%
45%
50%
55%
60%
65%
70%
75%
1989
1990
1991
1992
1993
1994
1995
1996
1997
1998
1999
2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
8
governments would receive the same proportion of the total federal budget as the prior
year, but a smaller quantity of funds; or ii) a decrease in the country or the state’s
population. Hence, as can be seen in Figure 5, federal transfers to sub-national governments
are influenced little by decreases in oil revenue. As a matter of fact, from 1990 to 2010,
federal transfers to sub-national governments grew by 194 percent. Total national revenue
from oil grew at a much slower pace, 83 percent, in the same period.
As the situation stands today, the federal government passes almost all of its oil
revenue to the sub-national governments. Indeed, from 1998 to 2003, revenue from oil
alone would have been insufficient to cover federal transfers to sub-national governments
(Figure 5). Additionally, under current circumstances, every reduction in oil prices is
absorbed by the federal government. That means that, in the case of a US$2.00 reduction in
oil prices, in order to fulfill restrictions of Fiscal Coordination Law, Federal government
would have to offset a reduction of 0.49 percent in municipal revenues. Combined with the
amount corresponding to states, this represents a reduction in the federal budget of 1
percent.
Figure 5. Oil Revenue vs. Federal Transfers
(in constant MXN millions)
Source: IMCO with data from INEGI and the Treasury Ministry (SHCP).
9
At first glance, such declines might not seem very drastic. However, history has
shown that oil prices tend to fall by much more than US$2.00 (Table 2). For example, in
1998 the average price of oil per barrel was 34 percent less than the price assumed in the
budget law. According to estimations by IMCO, using data from the economic criteria
forecasts published by the central government and the Law on Hydrocarbons, a decline of
US$10.00 in the budgeted price per barrel of oil would reduce the national budget by 5
percent. Figure 6 shows that the loss of revenue from such a decline would be equivalent to
two-thirds of the total public debt. To offset this loss, the base for the value-added tax
would have to be increased by 36 percent, or the rate would have to increase from 16
percent to 22 percent.
Table 2. Projected vs. Actual Oil Prices per Barrel,
1998-2008 Annual Averages
Official Expected
Oil Barrel Price
(USD)
Year Average
Oil Barrel Price
(USD)
Difference ( percent)
1998
$15.50
$10.18
-34
1999
$9.25
$15.57
68
2000
$15.00
$24.79
65
2001
$18.00
$18.61
3
2002
$15.50
$21.52
39
2003
$18.35
$24.77
35
2004
$20.00
$31.05
55
2005
$23.00
$42.71
86
2006
$36.50
$53.05
45
2007
$42.80
$61.63
44
2008
$49.00
$89.38
82
Source: IMCO with data from Pardinas (2009).
10
Figure 6. Impact of a US$10.00 per Barrel Decrease in Price of Oil
on the Federal Budget, 2010 (in MXN millions)
Source: IMCO with data from federal budget laws for 2010.
Note: Percentages represent the reduction of revenue due to a $10 USD loss.
Once the relationship between oil revenue and the Mexican governments’ finances
has been established and understood, a second question emerges. How feasible is a crisis
scenario in the Mexican oil industry? The answer is that it is a latent possibility. Figure 7
illustrates the perilous recent history of Mexico’s oil production. As of 2009, average daily
production of oil has fallen by 23 percent from its peak in 2004 and is now at production
levels similar to those observed in the early 1980s.
Figure 7. Daily Crude Oil Production, 1990-2010
(in thousands of barrels)
Source: IMCO with data from PEMEX.
$0
$200,000
$400,000
$600,000
$800,000
$1,000,000
Public Debt Value Added Tax Income Tax Oil
$10 USD Loss Revenue
2200
2400
2600
2800
3000
3200
3400
3600
1990
1991
1992
1993
1994
1995
1996
1997
1998
1999
2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
63%
36%
27%
17%
11
Estimates from the Mexican Institute of Competitiveness, based on a conservative
calculation of the behavior of oil demand and the decrease in production from oil deposits,
indicate that Mexico will become a net importer of crude oil by the year 2017 (Figure 8).
From then on, oil revenue will likely be replaced by oil expenditures. Under that scenario,
the Fiscal Coordination Law’s prohibition on reducing transfers in nominal terms might not
be sustainable; sub-national governments would be forced to find ways of raising revenues
independently to replace dwindling federal transfers.
Figure 8. Crude Oil Production and Demand, 2005-2025
(in thousands of barrels)
Source: IMCO estimates with data from PEMEX. *Estimated
3. Fiscal Autonomy of the States
Federal transfers to states are funded by federal taxes and royalties from oil revenues. They
are of two types: revenue sharing (Participaciones) and special purpose grants
(Aportaciones) which are earmarked for specific social services such as education, health
and public safety. These transfers have a horizontal nature, which means that subnational
units receive a pre-determined percentage of such transfers regardless of their individual
contributions to the fund (Recaudación Federal Participable). The initial objective of this
structure was to transfer resources from wealthier states to poorer states in order to promote
12
development. However, this structure has been counterproductive in regard to local tax
collection.
Aside from taxes that only the central government can collect, there are a variety of
taxes that can be introduced by state governments. However, each state decides the number,
coverage of the base, and rate structure for each tax, thus determining the amount of
potential revenue that could be raised.
Table 3. Number and Taxes of Each State for 2010
State
Number
of taxes
Payroll
tax
Lodging
tax
Tax on
lotteries
Tax on
acquisition
of used
motor
vehicles
Tax on
vehicle
ownership
Leisure and
entertainment
tax
Others
Aguascalientes
7
*
*
*
*
*
*
*
Baja California
8
*
*
*
*
*
Baja California Sur
4
*
*
*
*
Campeche
7
*
*
*
*
*
Coahuila
7
*
*
*
*
*
*
*
Colima
7
*
*
*
*
*
*
Chiapas
7
*
*
*
*
*
*
Chihuahua
9
*
*
*
*
*
D.F.
7
*
*
*
*
*
*
Durango
6
*
*
*
*
*
Guanajuato
7
*
*
*
*
*
Guerrero
9
*
*
*
*
*
*
Hidalgo
7
*
*
*
*
*
*
Jalisco
8
*
*
*
*
*
México
4
*
*
*
*
Michoacán
4
*
*
*
*
Morelos
9
*
*
*
*
*
*
*
Nayarit
12
*
*
*
*
*
*
Nuevo León
4
*
*
*
*
Oaxaca
8
*
*
*
*
*
*
*
Puebla
6
*
*
*
*
*
*
Querétaro
8
*
*
*
*
*
*
*
Quintana Roo
6
*
*
*
*
13
Table 3., continued
State
Number
of taxes
Payroll
tax
Lodging
tax
Tax on
lotteries
Tax on
acquisition
of used
motor
vehicles
Tax on
vehicle
ownership
Leisure and
entertainment
tax
Others
San Luis Potosí
7
*
*
*
*
*
*
Sinaloa
4
*
*
*
*
Sonora
5
*
*
*
Tabasco
6
*
*
*
*
*
Tamaulipas
5
*
*
*
*
Tlaxcala
8
*
*
*
*
*
*
*
Veracruz
5
*
*
*
*
*
Yucatán
7
*
*
*
*
*
*
Zacatecas
5
*
*
*
*
Source: IMCO with data from State Revenue Acts.
Between 2000 and 2008, tax revenue represented 42 percent of own state revenues,
while non-tax revenue (rights, land use, products, royalties, etc.) contributed the remaining
58 percent. The most important state tax is the payroll tax. In 2008, it represented 63.3
percent of the states’ total tax revenue. Its importance lies in the breadth and stability of its
tax base. This tax was introduced gradually across states, and since 2008, all states have
collected it. However, the tax regime is not the same in all the states; the main source of
variance is the difference in rates, which range between 1 and 2 percent.
Figure 9. Composition of States’ Total Tax Revenue, 2008
Source: IMCO with data from INEGI.
63.3%
28.1%
4.2%
4.4%
Payroll tax Direct taxes (excluding payroll tax) Indirect taxes Other taxes
14
As in the case of tax revenues, non-tax revenues take a variety of forms, and their
application varies across states. Among non-tax revenues, fees or derechos (mainly for
public and private transportation, business or property registration, civil registration, and
city services) are the most significant source of revenue, contributing 34 percent of local
revenues. The rest of local revenues are generated by capital gains, tax penalties, and
surcharges.
The tax on vehicle ownership deserves special mention because of recent legislative
changes. This tax is collected by the central government according to the vehicle registry of
each state. However, the revenue raised by this tax is returned to the state where the
vehicle is legally registered. In 2008, revenues from this tax represented 1.8 percent of total
states’ revenues, but this share varies among the states (Figure 10). This tax has been in
place since 1961, but in 2012, a federal decree removing it will take effect. However, the
decree allows the states to adopt it as a local tax.
Figure 10. Tax on Vehicle Ownership
as a Percent of Total Revenue, 2008
Source: IMCO with data from the Ministry of the Treasury and INEGI.
0.0%
0.5%
1.0%
1.5%
2.0%
2.5%
3.0%
3.5%
4.0%
4.5%
5.0%
Nuevo León
D. F.
Jalisco
Querétaro
Quintana Roo
Aguascalientes
Guanajuato
Baja California
Sinaloa
Yucatán
Coahuila
Sonora
México
Puebla
Tamaulipas
Chihuahua
San Luis Potosí
Colima
Morelos
Baja California Sur
Michoacán
Veracruz
Campeche
Durango
Tabasco
Hidalgo
Nayarit
Zacatecas
Guerrero
Chiapas
Tlaxcala
Oaxaca
15
4. Determinants of the Fiscal Effort of Mexican States: A Stochastic
Frontier Analysis
Most of the literature on fiscal effort consists of empirical studies. In this section we will
propose a stochastic frontier model for taxation capacity that will allow us to measure the
revenue-collecting effort of Mexican states, defined as the ratio of observed tax collection
to the potential collection at the efficiency frontier. Such frontiers establish a potential tax
collection given the fiscal unit economic characteristics and legal framework.
This exercise involving two procedures has been recognized as a useful but
inconsistent one mainly because of the underlying independence assumption. Battese and
Coeli (1985) proposed the model that will be used in this working paper to address that
issue.
In order to estimate the maximum likelihood estimators of the parameters, the
stochastic frontier estimation method consists of three steps:
1. First, we obtain the function Ordinary Least Squares estimators (OLS)
that produces parameters

All parameters will be unbiased with
the exception of the intercept
.
2. Using the
, parameters and the
and
parameters adjusted
according to the corrected ordinary least squares formula proposed by
Coelli (1995), a two-stage grid search of the parameter is conducted.
If there is any other parameter, it is set to zero in this stage.
3. To obtain the maximum likelihood estimators we use the values selected
in the grid search as starting values in an iterative maximization
procedure. Since we will use the software Frontier 4.1, this procedure
will be the Davidon-Fletcher-Powell Quasi-Newton method.
In order to explain the differences among states regarding government effort in tax
collection, the model includes some economic variables such as GDP per capita, the share
of industrial output in GDP, a coefficient of income inequality, and a measure of the
informal economy, which does not pay payroll taxes or fees for services (water, electricity,
etc.). We include fiscal variables, such as the share of central government transfers in total
revenue and public investment expenditure. We also consider political variables, such as
16
the governors political affiliation, and institutional variables, such as corruption and a good
governance index.
Given these assumptions, the model specification for the tax collection potential
(the stochastic frontier for total state tax revenues per capita) is the following:


 


  


  

, (1)
Similarly, we define the payroll tax function as follows:


 


  


  

, (2)
where:


Tax collection per capita in state in year


Payroll tax collection per worker in state in year


Economically active population (in both the formal and informal sector) as share
of total population of state in year


GDP per capita in state in year

Error term defined as follows:



 

, (3)
where the

are random variables, which are assumed to be independent and identically
distributed (iid) 
and independent of the

that are non-negative random
variables, assumed to account for technical inefficiency
5
in revenue raising and to be iid as
truncations at zero of the 

distribution where


and

is a  
vector of variables which may influence the effort of a local government and is a   
vector of parameter to be estimated. The panel of data need not be complete.
With the calculation of the maximum likelihood estimator in mind, we will replace
and
with
and we define

as did by Battese and Corra
5
Through this document the term “efficiency” will be substituted for “effort” since it makes more sense when
talking about government tax collection.
17
(1977). Note that  and thus this range can be searched to provide a good starting
value for use in an iterative maximization process.
Given the assumptions stated above regarding the error term, for (1) we define:










,
Similarly, for (2) we define:












,
where:


Share of industrial GDP in the GDP of state in year


Institutional Quality of Justice Index in state in year
6


Dummy that is 1 if the governor of state in year belongs to the political party of
the president and is 0 otherwise


Informality rate in state in year


Corruption and Good Government Index of state in year


Transparency Index of state in year

Error term
For both models, observations are for eight years (from 2001 to 2008). For (1) we
use a balanced panel with 256 observations, while for (2) we use an unbalanced panel with
216 observations, since during this period some states did not have a payroll tax and they
implemented it gradually.
Ex ante, for both functions we expect a positive sign in the two independent
variables, since the greater the economically active population or the economy’s output per
capita, the higher revenues should be. We also expect a positive sign for institutional
quality of justice and for the transparency index, since the greater the government
6
Consejo Coordinador Financiero, “Ejecución de Contratos Mercantiles e Hipotecas en las Entidades
Federativas Mexicanas.”
18
accountability perceived by the citizens, the more willing they are likely to be to pay taxes.
For the share of industrial GDP a positive sign is also expected, since it is easier to collect
from this sector. If the governor has the same political affiliation as the president, a
negative relation is expected, since we assume they would be favored with discretionary
transfers. Moreover, negative signs are expected for the informality rate and the corruption
and good governance index.
In order to determine if a stochastic frontier function is required, we tested the
significance of the parameter. For both models, the result determined that the null
hypothesis (that equals zero) would be rejected, indicating that
is not zero, and hence
the

should not be removed.
5. Analysis of Empirical Estimates
The robust variable of the model (1) is the GDP per capita, while for the effort measure of
this model, the industrial contribution to the total output and the corruption index were
significant and with the expected sign.
Table 4. Maximum Likelihood Estimators for the State Revenue Model
Coefficient
Standard-
error
t-ratio
P-value
beta 0
-13,99
0,87
-16,17
0,000
***
beta 1
0,68
1,39
0,49
0,627
***
beta 2
1,72
0,11
16,31
0,000
***
delta 0
-1,32
0,66
-1,99
0,047
***
delta 1
0,25
0,22
1,10
0,271
***
delta 2
7,61
1,08
7,03
0,000
***
delta 3
-0,00
0,01
-0,76
0,445
***
delta 4
-0,12
0,04
-2,87
0,004
***
sigma-squared
0,87
0,17
5,13
0,000
***
gamma
0,94
0,03
32,57
0,000
***
***
Significant 99%.
**
Significant 95%.
*
Significant 90%.
Source: Authors’ calculations.
19
Table 5. Mexican States’ Tax Collection Effort, 2001-2008 (percent)
State
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
Aguascalientes
9.5
10..8
11.8
13.5
18.4
34.3
56.4
55.5
Baja California
53.7
61.6
65.6
68.1
69.0
70.0
74.7
76.5
Baja California
Sur
50.5
37.1
47.8
50.9
76.1
83.3
86.0
85.8
Campeche
0.8
0.9
0.9
1.1
1.3
1.5
2.1
2.3
Chiapas
27.5
30.5
66.4
79.9
81.3
84.9
89.1
91.0
Chihuahua
77.0
78.8
79.0
77.9
79.5
80.6
82.3
82.6
Coahuila
20.7
22.4
19.9
20.2
22.4
21.7
24.3
26.7
Colima
10.8
11.8
12.0
12.1
49.3
55.4
61.4
60.4
Distrito Federal
88.5
88.5
89.1
88.5
90.4
89.5
89.1
89.9
Durango
33.0
36.4
38.5
35.0
38.7
64.9
67.9
67.8
Guanajuato
10.2
8.7
7.4
9.0
59.5
68.4
73.1
78.1
Guerrero
79.4
80.6
83.9
72.6
87.1
89.5
89.1
91.1
Hidalgo
28.6
29.4
47.1
50.4
55.5
66.2
65.0
80.6
Jalisco
44.9
47.6
49.2
50.3
53.4
54.7
57.4
60.7
México
72.9
82.5
81.9
79.8
79.8
83.4
91.2
91.6
Michoacán
16.9
19.2
45.6
45.6
56.1
65.4
68.7
64.4
Morelos
17.3
20.3
21.3
21.9
28.9
29.9
53.3
72.7
Nayarit
55.5
76.7
79.4
85.1
85.8
81.7
89.3
89.5
Nuevo León
33.7
35.7
36.1
35.3
37.1
36.5
35.6
39.2
Oaxaca
10.9
27.7
38.8
36.9
47.7
61.6
61.8
66.8
Puebla
36.6
46.9
51.2
48.2
48.0
65.1
73.3
75.0
Querétaro
12.6
15.1
14.6
14.1
61.8
74.1
74.0
77.5
Quintana Roo
52.2
53.9
62.4
67.0
65.5
66.9
72.1
79.4
San Luis Potosí
19.1
19.0
22.2
35.2
35.8
36.9
46.8
61.3
Sinaloa
33.2
35.2
38.1
37.8
41.0
46.4
47.2
60.3
Sonora
53.1
59.1
49.8
48.8
54.6
50.6
57.4
59.5
Tabasco
6.2
6.9
7.8
7.9
8.4
8.5
8.3
7.5
Tamaulipas
43.5
45.0
45.9
41.4
43.7
50.8
49.2
52.9
Tlaxcala
49.8
58.8
66.2
65.9
74.4
75.6
74.4
79.2
Veracruz
43.8
71.3
66.2
67.7
69.5
67.1
66.0
68.5
Yucatán
44.0
46.6
52.2
48.6
51.9
62.8
59.0
63.7
Zacatecas
58.3
66.0
67.5
65.8
73.4
75.7
79.8
80.9
Source: Authors’ calculation.
On average, tax collection effort increased by 29.5 percentage points between 2001
and 2008, from 37.3 percent to 66.8 percent, while average tax collection per capita
increased by 68.9 percent from MXN 221 in 2001 to MXN 374 in 2008. Using this
20
information and that provided by the model showing a positive relation between GDP and
tax collection, we can assume that growth in tax revenue is largely due to Mexico’s
economic growth before the 2008 crisis and to increased government tax effort during this
period.
7
For illustrative purposes, we will divide the states into three groups. In the first one
we will include those states whose average effort within this period is between the mean
and one standard deviation (  ), in the second one we will include those states whose
average effort is below one standard deviation (  ), and in the third one we will include
those states with average effort above one standard deviation (  ).
Figure 11. Spatial Distribution of Effort, 2001-2008 Average
Source: Authors’ compilation.
7
Between 2001 and 2008, the Mexican economy recorded cumulative real growth of 21 percent.
21
For a deeper analysis, we will divide Mexican states into four groups (Figure 12).
8
This division will allow us to distinguish between those states that have low tax collection
per capita because of their lack of effort from those which have low tax revenue because of
their narrow and limited tax base. Moreover, this distinction will also allow us to
distinguish between those states whose tax collection per capita is high because they make
an efficient tax effort from those which have high tax collection per capita because of
favorable economic conditions rather than collection efforts.
Figure 12. Mexican States’ Collection Effort vs. Tax Collection per Capita, 2008
Source: Authors’ calculations.
There is no surprise in regard to the states in Quadrants I and III, since we assume a
direct relation between effort and tax revenues. States in Quadrant II are those whose tax
collection effort is large, but they are not collecting much revenue from taxes. Quadrant II
includes Durango, Guerrero, Jalisco, Puebla, Tlaxcala, Veracruz, Yucatán, and Zacatecas.
The causes may be different for each state and may include issues such as ill-defined tax
8
For this analysis we exclude Distrito Federal since it is an outlier because of its different and broader taxing
powers and responsibilities.
77%
86%
2%
91%
83%
27%
68%
78%
91%
81%
92%
64%
73%
89%
39%
67%
75%
78%
79%
61%
60%
59%
7%
53%
79%
69%
64%
81%
0%
10%
20%
30%
40%
50%
60%
70%
80%
90%
100%
0 100 200 300 400 500 600 700 800
Tax Collection Effort
Tax Collection per Capita, MX pesos
Quadrant I
Quadrant II
Quadrant III
Quadrant IV
22
bases, many special regimes, or many exemptions, which restrict their possibility frontier.
The recommendation for these states is to promote structural changes in their taxation
systems.
On the other hand, Campeche,
9
Nuevo Leon, Sonora, and Tamaulipas are in
quadrant four: despite their low tax effort, they have a high tax collection per capita. These
states have a high potential for improvement since they seem to be exploiting their tax base
correctly. For Campeche, this phenomenon is caused by the large contribution of oil
production to its total output. For the other cases, this might be due to the large number of
firms that have decided to locate their logistics centers there because of its convenient
geographic location, thus facilitating tax collection with little effort. A hypothetical flight
of capital from the state could leave these states in dire financial straits since more than 10
percent of total revenue is own revenue. But at the same time, additional tax collection
effort by the government could generate significant additional revenue.
Figure 12. Mexican States’ Effort and Tax Collection per Capita, 2008
Source: Authors’ compilation.
Note: TCE refers to tax collection effort while TRPC refers to tax revenue per capita.
9
From here on, the analysis will not consider this state unless otherwise specified, since almost 85 percent of
its total output is due to oil.
23
With respect to the results of the model defined in (2) for the payroll tax function,
the results point in the same direction as those obtained for the total revenue function.
Once again, the robust variables include GDP per capita and for this model’s error term
almost all the variables were significant (except the corruption index) and with the expected
sign.
Table 6. Maximum Likelihood Estimators for the Payroll Tax Model
Coefficient
Standard-
error
t-ratio
P-value
beta 0
-13.13
0.96
-13.72
0.000
***
beta 1
-2.00
1.28
-1.56
0.119
***
beta 2
1.76
0.10
16.82
0.000
***
delta 0
-5.21
0.98
-5.32
0.000
***
delta 1
-8.08
1.98
-4.09
0.000
***
delta 2
8.17
0.85
9.60
0.000
***
delta 3
-0.05
0.03
-1.54
0.124
***
delta 4
1.46
0.32
4.62
0.000
***
delta 5
-1.39
0.38
-3.62
0.000
***
sigma-squared
0.48
0.07
6.91
0.000
***
gamma
0.66
0.06
11.10
0.000
***
***
Significant 99%.
**
Significant 95%.
*
Significant 90%
Source: Authors’ calculations.
As before, we compute the effort of Mexican states in payroll tax collection. The
results are shown in Table 7.
Table 7. Mexican States’ Effort for Payroll Tax Collection, 2001-2008 (percent)
State
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
Aguascalientes
N/A
N/A
N/A
N/A
N/A
63
87
90
Baja California
N/D
89
89
88
88
87
88
89
Baja California
Sur
76
78
82
85
89
91
91
89
Campeche
2
2
2
2
2
2
3
4
Chiapas
89
90
94
94
94
93
92
92
Chihuahua
85
84
86
86
84
82
86
87
Coahuila
N/D
N/D
46
43
48
36
39
44
Colima
N/A
N/A
N/A
N/A
79
77
82
85
Distrito Federal
92
92
92
92
93
91
90
92
Durango
59
63
65
62
67
68
72
74
24
Table 7., continued
State
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
Guanajuato
N/A
N/A
N/A
N/A
90
87
88
89
Guerrero
92
N/D
90
88
92
91
91
92
Hidalgo
76
72
80
77
81
73
74
84
Jalisco
92
92
93
92
92
90
91
92
México
N/D
N/D
91
90
91
89
92
92
Michoacán
N/D
N/D
87
89
91
91
90
90
Morelos
N/A
N/A
N/A
N/A
N/A
N/A
89
92
Nayarit
87
91
93
93
93
69
81
85
Nuevo León
87
88
87
75
74
59
64
75
Oaxaca
N/D
82
87
86
89
84
85
89
Puebla
N/D
89
89
88
88
91
92
92
Querétaro
N/A
N/A
N/A
N/A
87
90
88
89
Quintana Roo
87
87
88
88
87
83
89
90
San Luis Potosí
69
67
68
87
88
82
85
88
Sinaloa
83
84
85
84
84
80
80
84
Sonora
N/D
N/D
N/D
N/D
N/D
65
N/D
N/D
Tabasco
19
16
18
17
15
12
11
9
Tamaulipas
80
79
80
77
77
75
79
83
Tlaxcala
90
91
93
92
95
94
94
94
Veracruz
91
93
91
90
90
90
89
89
Yucatán
86
91
90
90
91
93
92
90
Zacatecas
81
82
82
78
78
80
81
80
Source: Authors’ calculation. N/A corresponds to cases in which the payroll tax
was not yet implemented in the state. N/D corresponds to cases in which there
was no official information available.
Table 7 shows that considerable effort is made to collect this tax in most states, and
has grown from 76.2 percent in 2001 to 81.1 percent in 2008, on average.
Using the data provided in Tables 5 and 7, we can divide the states into four groups.
25
Figure 13. Total Tax Collection Effort vs. Payroll Tax Collection Effort, 2008
10
Source: Authors’ calculation.
In Quadrant II are states such as Colima, Guanajuato, and Querétaro. They
implemented payroll taxes in 2005 as a source of sub-national revenue. The results suggest
that implementation of the payroll tax was successful, since their payroll tax collection
effort is high. However, the results also suggest that they overestimate its potential. These
three states are among the 10 with the lowest share of payroll tax in total revenue. These
states have room for improvement and can focus on the collection of other taxes so they can
increase their revenue. Also in this quadrant is Mexico City, which, although it has
different taxation powers and is exploiting the payroll tax efficiently, still has significant
opportunities for improvement in the collection of other taxes.
In quadrant four are states such as Durango and Zacatecas, which are also among
those states where the contribution of the payroll tax to total revenue is lowest. The results
suggest that even though these states are efficient in general with respect to total tax
collection, they have not managed payroll taxes properly, focusing their efforts instead on
10
Data for Sonora correspond to 2006, the latest available data.
40.0%
50.0%
60.0%
70.0%
80.0%
90.0%
100.0%
20.0% 30.0% 40.0% 50.0% 60.0% 70.0% 80.0% 90.0% 100.0%
Payroll tax effort
Total tax collection effort
Quadrant I
Quadrant II
Quadrant III
Quadrant IV
26
the collection of all other taxes. States in quadrants one and three have the expected
behavior: we expected a positive correlation between the effort in total tax collection and
effort regarding payroll tax collection.
For both models, it was surprising that employment was not a significant variable.
In the results of (1), EAP has a positive but not significant sign. This may suggest that
policies should be focusing on creating better-remunerated jobs rather than more low value-
added positions. The result of (2) is even more interesting, since it shows a negative
relationship between payroll tax and employment that is very close to the significance zone.
Some authors state that the payroll tax is a burden on a productive factor (labor) that
discourages the use of this factor in the formal sector. Even though this is a relevant and
quite important issue, it is beyond the scope of this project and requires further research.
6. Revenue Potential for Mexican States
What would happen if all states operated with 100 percent effort? In the following section
we will use the data obtained before to discuss a hypothetical scenario facing Mexican
states if they could raise all of the potential revenue.
First, we define the Fiscal Autonomy Index (FAI) as follows:





, (4)
where


Total revenue of state in year


Own revenue of state in year including not only tax revenue but other local
revenue as well.
The FAI tells us what proportion of total revenue is contributed by sub-national
governments. For this analysis, we will use 2008 data. Since no state has tax collection
that is 100 percent efficient, the potential FAI will be greater than the actual one. The
potential autonomy index will be computed by using potential tax collection in both total
revenue and own revenue.
27
Figure 14. Fiscal Autonomy Index, 2008
Source: Authors’ calculations.
Even if the potential is raised, fiscal autonomy will not increase significantly. The
FAI average would rise from 8.0 percent to 11.1 percent, suggesting that the weight of
central government transfers would remain very high. This is even more worrisome if we
exclude Mexico City and Campeche, since without them the average would only rise from
7.1 to 8.6 percent.
If we sort Mexican states according to their degree of fiscal autonomy and compare
the actual situation with the potential one, the state that would benefit the most in relative
terms is Tabasco, climbing almost 20 places,
11
followed by Coahuila and Tamaulipas,
advancing eight and three places, respectively. In the other direction, changes would not be
so dramatic, since those states that would fall in ranking would only do so by one or two
places.
At first, this would not create much additional revenue for the states, but given that
an important percentage of Participaciones distributed to the states depends on its own tax
collection efforts, those states for whom revenue increases more significantly would be
11
Tabasco is also one of the most important oil producers in the country, which is why, as in the case of
Campeche, the results are overstated.
0
0.05
0.1
0.15
0.2
0.25
0.3
0.35
0.4
Distrito Federal
Nuevo León
Chihuahua
Queretaro
Baja California
Quintana Roo
Tamaulipas
Coahuila
Tabasco
Sonora
Mexico
Baja California…
Sinaloa
Jalisco
Guanajuato
Aguascalientes
Hidalgo
Zacatecas
San Luis Potosí
Durango
Chiapas
Morelos
Michoacan
Puebla
Colima
Yucatan
Veracruz
Nayarit
Tlaxcala
Oaxaca
Guerrero
Potential FAI
Real FAI
28
rewarded in the next central government transfer allocation through the revenue-sharing
mechanism.
Even if all states raised their potential revenue and considering the situation faced
by Tabasco, the last three states would stay the same. This suggests that their dependence
on central government transfers would remain the same, as if they had made no extra effort
at all.
On average, states’ own revenue would only increase by 11.5 percent, and the share
of states’ own revenue in total tax revenue would increase from 41.2 to 56.1 percent.
Improving states’ efforts with their current tax bases would not be sufficient to substantially
strengthen the states’ public finances.
Figure 15. Share of Potential Tax Revenue in Potential States’ Own Revenue
Source: Authors’ calculations.
0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8
Campeche
Distrito Federal
Nuevo León
Chihuahua
Queretaro
Baja California
Quintana Roo
Tamaulipas
Coahuila
Tabasco
Sonora
Mexico
Baja California Sur
Sinaloa
Jalisco
Guanajuato
Aguascalientes
Hidalgo
Zacatecas
San Luis Potosí
Durango
Chiapas
Morelos
Michoacan
Puebla
Colima
Yucatan
Veracruz
Nayarit
Tlaxcala
Oaxaca
Guerrero
Current share
Potential Share
29
Table 8. Increase in States’ Own Revenue Assuming 100 Percent Effort, 2008
State
Increase (%)
Aguascalientes
33.32
Baja California
13.60
Baja California
Sur
7.84
Campeche
1795.14
Chiapas
2.58
Chihuahua
6.83
Coahuila
79.64
Colima
28.57
Distrito Federal
5.51
Durango
19.75
Guanajuato
13.15
Guerrero
5.39
Hidalgo
8.77
Jalisco
28.03
México
3.25
Michoacán
17.34
Morelos
14.37
Nayarit
7.14
Nuevo León
54.89
Oaxaca
9.90
Puebla
14.53
Querétaro
12.99
Quintana Roo
10.51
San Luis Potosí
25.63
Sinaloa
15.42
Sonora
19.98
Tabasco
256.01
Tamaulipas
37.75
Tlaxcala
8.18
Veracruz
23.62
Yucatán
29.15
Zacatecas
4.88
Source: Authors’ calculation.
Moreover, under the assumption of 100 percent effort by all states, the increase in
the states’ total revenue would be negligible.
30
Table 9. Increase in Total State Revenue Assuming 100 Percent Effort, 2008
State
Increase (%)
Aguascalientes
2.0
Baja California
1.5
Baja California
Sur
0.7
Campeche
134.7
Chiapas
0.2
Chihuahua
1.0
Coahuila
5.1
Colima
1.3
Distrito Federal
2.0
Durango
1.1
Guanajuato
1.0
Guerrero
0.2
Hidalgo
0.6
Jalisco
2.1
México
0.3
Michoacán
0.9
Morelos
0.8
Nayarit
0.3
Nuevo León
8.6
Oaxaca
0.4
Puebla
0.7
Querétaro
1.6
Quintana Roo
1.1
San Luis Potosí
1.4
Sinaloa
1.3
Sonora
1.8
Tabasco
8.4
Tamaulipas
3.2
Tlaxcala
0.3
Veracruz
0.9
Yucatán
1.1
Zacatecas
0.3
Source: Authors’ calculations.
We can see that most of the states would increase their total revenue by less than 2
percent. In fact, the average increase would be 5.8 percent but, if Mexico City and
Campeche are excluded, this average would be reduced to 1.7 percent. Moreover, even if
31
we assume a 100 percent effort and include Campeche’s figures, total own revenues would
grow by 33.7 percent, but total revenues would only grow by 3.5 percent.
The results suggest that state tax bases are in general being relatively well exploited,
especially the payroll tax base. The empirical evidence shows that the performance of
government institutions regarding revenue collection is generally acceptable. By comparing
the real and potential revenue of Mexican states, we can observe that there is not much
room for improvement in terms of tax collection. Given the current tax bases, even if they
could achieve their potential, the benefits would be very limited and would not provide
much in terms of total state revenues.
7. The Fiscal Autonomy of Municipalities
12
Fiscal centralism in Mexico has experienced historical ups and downs. In the late
nineteenth and early twentieth centuries, sub-national governments, both states and
municipalities, were relatively more important vis-à-vis the central government. In 1900,
municipal revenue exceeded 1 percent of GDP, but in the 1930s and 1940s, after the first
National Tax Convention, it decreased to about 0.5 percent of GDP.
13
The ratio of
municipal revenue has remained at this level for almost 70 years, and today it is actually
close to 0.4 percent of GDP (Figure 16). Mexico is at the bottom relative to OECD
countries, where the average revenue collection at this level of government is nearly 3
percent of GDP.
14
12
For this section, Mexico City is excluded from the analysis unless otherwise specified.
13
Díaz-Cayeros (2006: 37).
14
OCDE, Revenue Statistics 1965-2007.
32
Figure 16. Central Government, State and Municipal Tax Revenues
(as percent of GDP, 1990-2007)
Source: INEGI, World Bank, Díaz Cayeros (2006).
The main sources of municipal revenue are:
Exploitation of capital assets
Contributions enacted through local laws
Fees for the provision of public services
Central government transfers
Municipalities have no authority to decide which taxes to levy, although some
authority in this area is granted by local laws approved by state congresses. Municipalities
cannot create taxes and collect them on their own, but they can administer the revenue
sources that have been decided by local congresses. State revenue acts and state tax codes
regulate municipal tax bases.
Two of the pillars of municipal revenues are property taxes and water rights.
Between 2001 and 2008, property taxes accounted for almost 57 percent of municipal tax
revenues and more than 27 percent of own municipal revenues.
0%
2%
4%
6%
8%
10%
12%
1990
1991
1992
1993
1994
1995
1996
1997
1998
1999
2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
Municipios
Estados y DF
Federación
Tax Coordination Law
Municipalities
State governments
Federal government
33
Figure 17. Composition of Own Municipal Revenues
(average, 2001-2008)
Source: IMCO with data from INEGI.
The expenditure decentralization policy has influenced property tax collection.
Rising central government transfers sapped incentives to collect taxes. In 2008, the central
government tried to reverse the situation by including economic efficiency criteria in the
revenue-sharing formula. Internationally, in 2008, Mexico was the OECD country with the
lowest property tax collection rate as a percentage of GDP.
27%
21%
25%
7%
18%
2%
Property tax Other taxex Rights Products Exploitations Contributions
34
Figure 18. Property Tax as Percent of GDP, 2008
Source: OECD revenue statistics.
Cadastral updates have significantly improved property tax collection. With the
changes in the agricultural legislation in 1992 and the updating of property values, the share
of property tax in total revenue reached 10 percent in 1994. However, it fell back to
previous levels subsequently, following the increase in federal transfers.
Figure 19. Share of Property Tax in Total Revenue
Source: IMCO with data from INEGI.
0
0.5
1
1.5
2
2.5
3
3.5
4
4.5
United Kingdom
Canada
France
Israel
Korea
United States
Japan
Luxembourg
Spain
Australia
Belgium
Iceland
Switzerland
Denmark
Italy
New Zealand
Ireland
OECD - Total
Netherlands
Greece
Portugal
Chile
Norway
Poland
Finland
Sweden
Germany
Hungary
Turkey
Slovenia
Austria
Czech Republic
Slovak Republic
Mexico
5.5%
6.0%
6.5%
7.0%
7.5%
8.0%
8.5%
9.0%
9.5%
10.0%
10.5%
1989
1990
1991
1992
1993
1994
1995
1996
1997
1998
1999
2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009*
Tax Coordination Law
35
In 2008, 537 of the 2,456 municipalities (22 percent) did not levy property taxes or
did not report doing so. Eighty percent of all property tax revenue was collected by only
105 municipalities (4 percent). In fact, only 29 of the more than 2,400 municipalities
collect more than 50 percent of their total revenue; the rest depend on transfers from their
states or the central government.
Figure 20. Distribution of Own Municipal Revenues
as a Percent of Total Expenditure, 2008
Source: IMCO using data from INEGI.
Municipalities have a potential margin in revenue capacity that has not been fully
exploited. These are property taxes and water rights. However, land records and the tap-
water infrastructure would need to be updated. Even if not intended to become a source of
income, water rights should cover at least the cost of provision, to avoid giving rise to
deficits.
Given municipalities’ limited access to credit, the share of debt in total revenues
chas remained below 10 percent and has followed a downward trajectory. There is a
possibility to raise resources through debt, but the rules and circumstances under which
debt can be incurred would need to be established, since even in local laws, different
criteria are applied with respect to municipal debt contracting.
1561
439
208
135
66
20
9
0% - 9% 10% - 19% 20% - 29% 30% - 39% 40% - 49% 50% - 59% more than
60%
36
Added to this, municipalities have another issue to solve. Mayors in Mexico serve
only three-year terms, one of the shortest in Latin America, and immediate re-election is
prohibited. This situation causes inefficiencies because the learning curve is long, and in
their short terms, mayors and tax administrators do not have enough time to develop needed
skills. Moreover, they have little incentive to undertake projects with only long-term
payoffs.
Figure 21. Local Government Terms and the Possibility of Reelection
*In Coahuila, local government terms were lengthened to four years in 2006.
Source: Pardinas (2009).
8. Fiscal Effort in Mexican Municipalities: A Stochastic Frontier Analysis
Following the same methodology used in the sections above for Mexican states, we carried
out a stochastic frontier analysis for both total own-source revenues and property tax
revenues of Mexican municipalities. Since the information for municipalities is more
limited and certain information is not available for all of them, the results will be reported
as averages.
The literature on fiscal effort in municipalities is scarce, and most of the studies
consider the sums by state of both total tax revenue and property tax, so that a more
2
3
4
5
6
Nicaragua
Bolivia
Guatemala
Panama
Paraguay
Uruguay
Argentina
Brazil
Chile
Colombia
Costa Rica
Ecuador
Haiti
Honduras
Perú
República…
Venezuela
El Salvador
México*
Reelection
No reelection
37
accurate and complete panel can be used. However, we prefer not to do this since such
analyses assume perfect cooperation agreements between municipalities of the same state
and do not consider some differences among municipalities of the same state (political
affiliation, for example) or the particular situations of each municipality (if they are rural or
not, or if they are coastal, at borders or inside the Mexican territory, for example). Despite
these potential problems, our methodology will allow us to report municipal efficiencies
grouped by state as well as on average.
As we did for states, we define the own municipal revenues function as follows:


 


  


  

, (5)
Similarly, we define the property tax function as follows:


 


  


  

, (6)
where:


Tax collection per capita in municipality in year


Property tax collection per capita in municipality in year


Economic Dependency Ratio defined as the share of 0-14 years and over 64 years
population of 15-64 in municipality in year


GDP per capita in municipality in year
As done earlier and given the assumptions of the previous sections, for (5) and (6)
we define:






,
where:


Molinar Concentration Index
15
in the municipality in year
15
The Molinar Concentration Index is a measurement of effective number of political parties in a party
system (Molinar, 1991). This index is defined as follows:
38


Dummy that is 1 if the major of the municipality in year belongs to the political
party of the state’s governor and is 0 otherwise

Error term
For both models, observations are for three years (from 2006 to 2008), and we use a
balanced panel with 1,071 observations from 357 municipalities (Appendix 1).
16
Ex ante, for both models we expect a similar behavior: a negative relationship of the
economic dependency ratio with tax collection because, the bigger the ratio, the greater the
pressure on potential workers to support those who cannot work, and a positive relationship
between GDP per capita and tax collection, as we expected for the states’ model. For the
political concentration index we expect a positive sign, since a more competitive political
environment may force elected mayors to be more efficient. For the political party of the
mayor, we expect that municipalities with mayors belonging to the same political party as
the governor collect less since, as in the states’ case, they can be favored with discretionary
transfers.
As in the case of the states, the parameter proved to be non-zero for both models,
pointing to the significance of the effort component in the model’s total variance.
9. Results and Estimations Analysis for Mexican Municipalities
First of all, results may overestimate the real effort, since the municipalities selected are the
ones with stronger economic activity and for which information is available.
For the model defined in (5), all variables for both the stochastic frontier and the
effort measure are robust and with the expected sign. Central government transfers, GDP
per capita, and the economic dependency ratio had the expected sign.
   


 

where

16
In 2008, these municipalities contributed with 87 percent of total tax revenue and 85 percent of total
property tax revenue. Moreover, together they accounted for 66 percent of GDP and 57 percent of the
population.
39
Table 10. Maximum Likelihood Estimators for the Own Municipal
Revenues Function
Coefficient
Standard-
error
t-ratio
P-value
beta 0
6.95
0.66
10.6
0.000***
beta 1
-6.86
0.54
-12.7
0.000***
beta 2
0.24
0.05
5.2
0.000***
delta 0
-46.86
11.78
-4.0
0.000***
delta 1
3.86
0.73
5.3
0.000***
delta 2
-17.49
3.97
-4.4
0.000***
sigma-squared
61.87
15.20
4.1
0.000***
gamma
0.99
0.00
349.2
0.000***
***
Significant 99%.
**
Significant 95%.
*
Significant 90%
Source: Authors’ calculations.
Municipalities are collecting only almost half of their potential. Between 2006 and
2008, municipal tax collection effort grew by only 1 percent, from 45 percent in 2006 to 46
percent in 2008.
17
However, the effort varies among types of municipalities.
Table 11. Municipal Effort
(percent)
2006
2007
2008
Total (average)
45
43
46
Border (average)
62
62
62
Port (average)
57
58
58
Inland (average)
44
42
45
Source: Authors’ calculations.
Table 11 shows that border and port municipalities show significantly more effort in
tax collection than inland ones.
As above, an analysis grouping municipal tax collection effort can be made by state.
Table 12 summarizes the results.
17
According to the model, municipalities experienced a decrease in their effort level during 2007 in such way
that they registered an effort equivalent to 43 percent.
40
Table 12. Municipal Tax Collection Effort Grouped by State
(percent)
State
2006
2007
2008
Aguascalientes
69.6
71.6
67.6
Baja California
65.2
65.0
67.0
Baja California
Sur
71.6
72.2
72.8
Campeche
45.7
45.3
46.0
Coahuila
60.6
61.2
58.8
Colima
49.9
51.6
55.2
Chiapas
40.9
36.9
37.7
Chihuahua
60.0
64.4
65.1
Durango
58.4
58.6
60.3
Guanajuato
60.7
61.0
61.2
Guerrero
60.4
59.5
57.8
Hidalgo
48.0
47.7
48.2
Jalisco
65.8
66.0
65.9
México
48.2
50.4
50.7
Michoacán
54.8
54.4
51.3
Morelos
60.4
61.3
62.1
Nayarit
60.7
61.7
60.7
Nuevo León
66.8
65.3
65.1
Oaxaca
10.2
17.3
24.2
Puebla
32.2
19.6
21.0
Querétaro
72.0
73.5
73.4
Quintana Roo
73.5
73.9
71.0
San Luis Potosí
51.4
55.1
54.1
Sinaloa
64.2
65.4
66.1
Sonora
61.9
62.9
65.3
Tabasco
28.2
28.4
29.4
Tamaulipas
52.6
52.7
53.3
Tlaxcala
19.2
6.5
17.7
Veracruz
41.3
39.0
41.7
Yucatán
40.5
36.8
42.6
Zacatecas
50.8
49.9
47.0
Source: Authors’ calculations.
With respect to the results of model (6), all the variables are robust and with the
expected signs.
41
Table 13. Maximum Likelihood Estimator for the Property Tax Function
Coefficient
Standard-
error
t-ratio
P-value
beta 0
5.91
0.53
11.2
0.000
***
beta 1
-4.99
0.43
-11.5
0.000
***
beta 2
0.19
0.04
5.1
0.000
***
delta 0
-46.19
14.78
-3.1
0.002
***
delta 1
2.18
0.63
3.5
0.001
***
delta 2
-21.67
5.66
-3.8
0.000
***
sigma-squared
68.52
20.43
3.4
0.001
***
gamma
0.99
0.00
510.6
0.000
***
***
Significant 99%.
**
Significant 95%.
*
Significant 90%
Source: Authors’ calculations.
The data show that between 2006 and 2008, the property tax collection effort did
not grow significantly. Moreover, the results are quite similar to those we get for the total
municipal tax revenue. This likely reflects both the fact that the property tax is the one with
the heaviest weight in municipal tax revenues and that the specifications are the same for
both equations.
As for total tax revenue, property tax revenue varies among different types of
municipalities.
Table 14. Municipal Property Tax Effort 2006-08
(percent)
2006-2008
Total (average)
53
Border municipalities (average)
61
Port municipalities (average)
60
Inland municipalities (average)
52
Source: Authors’ calculations.
Again, it seems that border and port municipalities make a more significant effort
than inland ones. However, this effort did not improve during the three years analyzed.
Grouping by state, we can detect where municipal effort is weakest. Table 15
shows the average effort between 2006 and 2008.
42
Table 15. Property Tax Effort Grouped by State 2006-08
(percent)
State
2006
2007
2008
Aguascalientes
64.3
63.2
59.8
Baja California
61.0
60.6
66.7
Baja California
Sur
65.8
65.9
68.4
Campeche
48.0
47.1
45.9
Coahuila
58.7
55.1
56.5
Colima
56.3
57.6
60.1
Chiapas
23.2
11.7
10.6
Chihuahua
66.2
64.8
66.8
Durango
58.7
58.2
60.0
Guanajuato
67.9
68.1
61.9
Guerrero
57.3
54.2
48.2
Hidalgo
51.6
49.5
51.0
Jalisco
66.1
66.4
66.6
México
48.7
52.6
52.8
Michoacán
56.0
57.9
63.5
Morelos
50.6
57.4
57.3
Nayarit
58.2
59.0
65.9
Nuevo León
67.6
65.5
60.8
Oaxaca
9.4
15.3
22.5
Puebla
32.9
20.1
27.1
Querétaro
71.4
73.9
71.2
Quintana Roo
76.0
74.9
57.9
San Luis Potosí
47.0
51.7
59.6
Sinaloa
67.2
67.8
66.9
Sonora
54.3
63.1
55.3
Tabasco
25.6
25.9
33.9
Tamaulipas
56.3
51.5
48.3
Tlaxcala
21.1
6.0
21.5
Veracruz
43.9
41.3
43.0
Yucatán
19.6
20.8
32.3
Zacatecas
47.2
46.5
27.4
Source: Authors’ calculations.
Note that three of the four most inefficient states are among those with the largest number
of municipalities, such as Oaxaca (570), Puebla (217), and Chiapas (119).
43
By combining Tables 12 and 15, we can distinguish by state between municipalities
that exploit other taxes in addition to the property tax from those that rely on the property
tax exclusively for financing.
Figure 22. Property Tax Collection Effort vs. Municipal Tax Collection Effort
2006-2008 (grouped by state)
Source: Authors’ calculations.
Figure 23 supports the evidence that most municipal governments rely exclusively
on the property tax (in the best-case scenario) and do not properly exploit other tax bases.
However, it also draws attention to the case of Chiapas where, although the property tax
collection effort was 15.1 percent, total tax collection effort averaged 38.5 percent from
2006 to 2008.
0.00%
20.00%
40.00%
60.00%
80.00%
100.00%
0.00% 20.00% 40.00% 60.00% 80.00% 100.00%
Total tax collection effort
Property tax collection effort
44
Figure 23. Composition of Municipal Tax Revenues in Chiapas,
(average 2006-2008)
Source: IMCO using data from INEGI.
Figure 24 shows that municipalities in the state of Chiapas exploited other tax bases
in addition to the property tax. However, it is not possible to know which taxes those were,
is since they reported this revenue as “other taxes.”
10. Revenue Potential for Mexican Municipalities
This section will attempt to answer the same question asked with respect to state revenues.
What would happen if all municipalities operated at 100 percent effort? The data obtained
previously will be used to discuss a hypothetical scenario facing Mexican municipalities if
they could increase their potential revenue.
16.8%
7.9%
0.3%
75.0%
Property tax Transfer of title (real state) Services provision Other taxes
45
Table 16. Increase in Own Municipal Revenue Grouped by State
Assuming a 100 Percent Effort, 2008
State
Increase (%)
Aguascalientes
54
Baja California
95
Baja California Sur
78
Campeche
71
Coahuila
81
Colima
58
Chiapas
112
Chihuahua
85
Durango
57
Guanajuato
78
Guerrero
86
Hidalgo
102
Jalisco
56
México
110
Michoacán
63
Morelos
95
Nayarit
81
Nuevo León
94
Oaxaca
148
Puebla
172
Querétaro
86
Quintana Roo
77
San Luis Potosí
82
Sinaloa
81
Sonora
93
Tabasco
122
Tamaulipas
99
Tlaxcala
183
Veracruz
102
Yucatán
129
Zacatecas
54
Source: Authors’ calculations.
Table 17 shows that own municipal revenues could be significantly increased if all
of the potential tax revenue could be collected. Under this scenario, eight states could more
than double their own revenues. Furthermore, total municipal revenue could also be
significantly increased.
46
Table 17. Increase in Total Municipal Revenue Grouped by State,
Assuming 100 Percent Effort, 2008
State
Increase
(%)
Aguascalientes
12
Baja California
36
Baja California
Sur
42
Campeche
8
Coahuila
20
Colima
16
Chiapas
5
Chihuahua
28
Durango
11
Guanajuato
16
Guerrero
17
Hidalgo
14
Jalisco
19
Mexico
22
Michoacán
10
Morelos
24
Nayarit
18
Nuevo León
29
Oaxaca
12
Puebla
22
Querétaro
23
Quintana Roo
31
San Luis Potosí
11
Sinaloa
28
Sonora
27
Tabasco
11
Tamaulipas
14
Tlaxcala
15
Veracruz
12
Yucatán
20
Zacatecas
8
Source: Authors’ calculations.
Unlike the case of the states, if municipalities exploited their potential tax bases,
their revenues would increase significantly: total own municipal revenue would rise by 108
percent and total municipal revenue by 23 percent.
47
Regarding the property tax, if all municipalities operated at 100 percent effort,
Mexico could jump four places from the bottom of the ranking of OECD countries,
collecting the equivalent of 0.65 percent of GDP. However, even assuming a 100 percent
effort, Mexico would still be far below the OECD average (1.8 percent).
Figure 24. Potential Property Tax as a Percentage of GDP, 2008
Source: Authors’ calculations with data from OECD revenue statistics
Figure 24 shows a clear need to update cadastral values and to invest in land
regularization if Mexico wants to improve its ranking within the OECD.
The conclusion reached by the municipal analysis is the opposite of the one reached
for the states. The result suggests that municipal tax bases are not being fully exploited.
Even the property tax, which is the most important and the easiest to collect, has a poor
collection rate. The empirical evidence shows that the performance of municipal
government institutions regarding revenue collection is deficient. By comparing the real
and potential revenues of Mexican municipalities, it is evident that there is huge scope for
improvement in terms of tax collection.
0
0.5
1
1.5
2
2.5
3
3.5
4
4.5
United Kingdom
Canada
France
Israel
Korea
United States
Japan
Luxembourg
Spain
Australia
Belgium
Iceland
Switzerland
Denmark
Italy
New Zealand
Ireland
OECD - Total
Netherlands
Greece
Portugal
Chile
Norway
Poland
Finland
Sweden
Germany
Hungary
Turkey
Mexico
Slovenia
Austria
Czech Republic
Slovak Republic
48
11. More Taxing Authority to the States
11.1 The Case of the VAT
The value-added tax (VAT) is a tax levied by the central government which represents an
important share of non-oil tax revenues. Under the current tax coordination scheme, all
VAT collection (along with other sources of federal revenue) is deposited in a fund known
as recaudación federal participable (RFP). This fund is redistributed among the states
according to certain criteria specified in the fiscal coordination law.
This section examines the implications of allowing the states to share the VAT base
with the federal government. Under a tax scheme that allows both a federal and state rate
for the VAT, own state revenues would increase.
18
However, if the total VAT rate is not
allowed to rise, and the tax base is not extended, transfers under the participaciones would
be smaller and some states’ total revenue would decline, while some others’ revenue would
rise depending on their revenue potential under the VAT.
This two-rate scheme can be proposed in many ways. Trigueros and Fernández
(2001)
19
proposed a scheme in which the federal rate is fixed at 12 percent and the states are
allowed to apply a tax rate up to 6 percent. This scheme also sets a limit of 25 percent for
fiscal credits, so that the central government does not lose a large amount of resources, and
consumers would be subject to rates between 12 percent (when local governments do not
exercise the option to tax) and 15 percent (when local governments decide to tax at a rate of
6 percent).
20
For the sake of simplicity, we will assume that there is no net negative balance of
interstate credits and the VAT rate is split into a federal rate of 12 percent and a state rate of
3 percent.
21
We also assume that the amount of federal VAT and the rest of the
participaciones are allocated to states at the same rate observed for central government
transfers in the year analyzed. Implicitly we are assuming that all states are as effective as
18
In the case where some states have negative VAT balance, which means they have to refund a higher
amount than what they received in taxes at the end of the fiscal year, their own revenue would decrease
because the state will absorb a part of the subsidy instead of sharing all tax burdens with other states.
19
The authors favor a comprehensive reform, including expanding the VAT base, among other measures.
However, they assess the impact of this reform on the federal budget, not on sub-national ones.
20
The maximum rate for the local tax is fixed at 6 percent because a higher rate would result in an equivalent
VAT rate above 15 percent due to the limit in tax credits.
21
We selected the rate of 15 percent since there was no complete information for 2010 to perform this
exercise with a rate of 16 percent. The special regime of border areas is not considered since there are no
disaggregated data available at that level.
49
the central government at VAT collection and that the VAT base is the same. However,
given that some states could be more effective than others, it would make sense if the
federal government is responsible for collecting the state VAT surcharge while still
allowing the states to choose the rate charged.
Considering the scenario described above, it is not of interest to study the case in
which all states choose not to implement a VAT surcharge, since to allocate a smaller fund
without having other revenue sources will reduce the total revenue of all states. We will
focus our study on the case in which all states decide to implement a 3 percent surcharge on
12 percent of the federal VAT rate. Table 18 summarizes the effect of this surcharge on the
own revenue of each state.
Table 18. Change in Own Revenue with a Local VAT Rate of 3 Percent, 2008
State
Change (%)
Aguascalientes
92.4
Baja California
75.6
Baja California
Sur
25.0
Campeche
42.2
Coahuila
44.0
Colima
848.4
Chiapas
5.6
Chihuahua
27.6
Distrito Federal
109.2
Durango
2.7
Guanajuato
16.9
Guerrero
20.8
Hidalgo
11.5
Jalisco
52.7
México
22.7
Michoacán
36.5
Morelos
39.1
Nayarit
22.6
Nuevo León
74.8
Oaxaca
14.3
Puebla
16.4
Querétaro
6.2
Quintana Roo
24.7
San Luis Potosí
-10.3
50
Table 18., continued
State
Change (%)
Sinaloa
17.1
Sonora
32.6
Tabasco
26.8
Tamaulipas
533.3
Tlaxcala
2.4
Veracruz
202.0
Yucatán
50.5
Zacatecas
16.9
Source: Authors’ calculations.
The increases would be largest in states such as Colima, Distrito Federal,
Tamaulipas, and Veracruz, which make the largest contribution to the total VAT collection
and already have a large collection of this tax. Table 19 shows the impact of the proposed
reform on states’ total revenues.
Table 19. Change in Total Revenues with a Local VAT Rate of 3 Percent, 2008
State
Change (%)
Aguascalientes
-3.3
Baja California
0.0
Baja California
Sur
-5.8
Campeche
-4.4
Coahuila
-5.0
Colima
29.3
Chiapas
-8.5
Chihuahua
-3.4
Distrito Federal
32.8
Durango
-8.4
Guanajuato
-7.0
Guerrero
-8.1
Hidalgo
-8.0
Jalisco
-4.1
México
-4.3
Michoacán
-7.1
Morelos
-6.8
Nayarit
-7.6
Nuevo León
3.7
51
Table 19., continued
State
Change (%)
Oaxaca
-8.5
Puebla
-7.8
Querétaro
-7.5
Quintana Roo
-4.7
San Luis Potosí
-9.4
Sinaloa
-7.2
Sonora
-4.6
Tabasco
-8.2
Tamaulipas
36.0
Tlaxcala
-8.3
Veracruz
-1.0
Yucatán
-6.9
Zacatecas
-7.3
Source: Authors’ calculations.
The information in both tables clearly shows that a measure intended to increase the
fiscal autonomy of states results in a net loss of revenue for most of them. Table 19 shows
that with this distribution agreement, only four of the 32 states would be favored, 27 would
be negatively affected, and one state would remain the same. In fact, this information
provides evidence that, with shares in total VAT collection of 49.3 percent, 16.1 percent,
and 6 percent, respectively. Distrito Federal, Tamaulipas, and Nuevo León are supporting
the other states.
Figure 25. Fiscal Autonomy Index with a Local VAT Rate, 2008
Source: Authors’ calculations.
52
Figure 25 illustrates the FAI defined in (4) for this tax proposal. As mentioned
earlier, the average value of the fiscal autonomy index increases by 5.2 percent, from 8
percent to 13.2 percent. However, total revenues of those states that are harmed would
decrease by 6.4 percent on average. On the other hand, the total revenues of favored states
would increase by 25.5 percent on average.
The variance in the impact of a VAT surcharge across states reflects both their
current dependence on central government transfers and their share in participaciones.
Under this proposal, states would strive to reduce tax evasion and/or levy the surcharge at a
higher rate if they do not want to see their financial position undermined, since the new
local nature of a percentage of the VAT revenue would cause a 9.4 percent reduction in the
participaciones.
Moreover, for this exercise it is also possible to consider an extension of the tax
base.
22
We will show the effect of two proposals for a tax base extension combined with
the above-mentioned surcharge.
The first one was proposed in 2011
23
by a senator from the Institutional
Revolutionary Party (PRI) and includes taxing products such as meat in natural state, dry
pasta, sugar, salt, oil, and tuna, among others. Table 20 summarizes the changes in own
state revenues.
22
In order to perform this exercise, extra assumptions should be made: we will assume that the entire tax is
paid by the final consumer and changes in consumptions patterns arising from changes in tax rates will not be
considered. This assumption also implies no budget constraints.
23
We do not consider the whole reform, just the exempt basket proposed and the new products to be taxed.
Since there was no information for expenditure during 2010 when this research was conducted, we modeled
the changes in the base for 2008 and kept the prevailing rate of 15 percent in that year. The full initiative is
available at http://www.senadorbeltrones.com/prensa/noticias/10-de-marzo-iniciativa-de-reforma-hacendaria-
del-gppi
53
Table 20. Change in Own Revenue with a Local VAT Rate of 3 Percent
Considering the PRI’s 2011 Proposal, 2008
State
Change (%)
Aguascalientes
96.1
Baja California
78.3
Baja California Sur
27.1
Campeche
44.4
Coahuila
46.8
Colima
853.5
Chiapas
7.9
Chihuahua
28.8
Distrito Federal
109.7
Durango
6.5
Guanajuato
19.6
Guerrero
25.8
Hidalgo
13.6
Jalisco
55.9
México
24.5
Michoacán
40.3
Morelos
44.1
Nayarit
27.5
Nuevo León
76.2
Oaxaca
18.5
Puebla
20.1
Querétaro
8.2
Quintana Roo
26.4
San Luis Potosí
-6.0
Sinaloa
21.2
Sonora
35.0
Tabasco
29.6
Tamaulipas
536.0
Tlaxcala
4.7
Veracruz
208.4
Yucatán
56.5
Zacatecas
19.3
Source: Authors’ calculation.
Again, we should know the impact of the measure on statestotal revenues to assess
whether or not to apply it. Changes in total revenue are shown in Table 21.
54
Table 21. Change in Total Revenue with a Local VAT Rate of 3 Percent
Considering the PRI’s 2011 Proposal, 2008
State
Change (%)
Aguascalientes
-2.2
Baja California
1.1
Baja California Sur
-4.8
Campeche
-3.5
Coahuila
-4.0
Colima
30.4
Chiapas
-7.5
Chihuahua
-2.4
Distrito Federal
33.6
Durango
-7.4
Guanajuato
-5.9
Guerrero
-7.0
Hidalgo
-7.0
Jalisco
-3.1
México
-3.4
Michoacán
-6.0
Morelos
-5.7
Nayarit
-6.6
Nuevo León
4.8
Oaxaca
-7.5
Puebla
-6.7
Querétaro
-6.5
Quintana Roo
-3.7
San Luis Potosí
-8.3
Sinaloa
-6.0
Sonora
-3.7
Tabasco
-7.2
Tamaulipas
37.1
Tlaxcala
-7.3
Veracruz
0.1
Yucatán
-5.8
Zacatecas
-6.3
Source: Authors’ calculations.
Considering the local surcharge of 3 percent and an extension of the VAT base as
proposed by the PRI, on average six states would increase their total revenue by 17.8
percent, while 26 states would reduce theirs by 5.6 percent. Even though this reform would
55
increase the total VAT collection by almost 3 percent, the redistributable funds would be
8.5 percent lower than the current ones.
Figure 26. Fiscal Autonomy Index with a Local VAT Rate
Considering the PRI’s 2011 Proposal, 2008
Source: Authors’ calculations.
Under this scenario, the average value of the FAI would be 13.3 percent, only 0.1
percent higher than in the previous scenario, where no changes to the tax base were made.
Furthermore, this scenario increases own state revenues by 79 percent and total revenues by
1 percent. Note that the increase of total revenues is quite similar to that which would be
obtained by raising tax collection to its full potential.
Similar to the last scenario, we propose another variation applying VAT to the
products that currently are not taxed and meet one of the following requirements: i) foods
that went through any refining process, or ii) consumption by high-income sectors is more
frequent than by low-income sectors. Changes in own revenue are summarized in Table 22.
0%
10%
20%
30%
40%
50%
60%
Distrito Federal
Tamaulipas
Colima
Nuevo León
Chihuahua
Baja California
Quintana Roo
Querétaro
México
Sonora
Baja California Sur
Jalisco
Aguascalientes
Veracruz
Campeche
Sinaloa
Coahuila
Guanajuato
Zacatecas
Hidalgo
Morelos
Michoacán
Chiapas
Puebla
Yucatán
Durango
San Luis Poto
Nayarit
Oaxaca
Guerrero
Tabasco
Tlaxcala
Potential FAI
Real FAI
56
Table 22. Changes in Own Revenue with a Local VAT Rate of 3 Percent
Considering the IMCO’s Exempt Basket Proposal, 2008
State
Change (%)
Aguascalientes
109.3
Baja California
87.8
Baja California Sur
33.7
Campeche
49.0
Coahuila
55.1
Colima
865.4
Chiapas
12.6
Chihuahua
33.5
Distrito Federal
112.8
Durango
13.9
Guanajuato
28.7
Guerrero
36.1
Hidalgo
19.9
Jalisco
67.2
México
31.0
Michoacán
49.1
Morelos
58.2
Nayarit
37.2
Nuevo León
83.2
Oaxaca
29.4
Puebla
30.8
Querétaro
15.0
Quintana Roo
35.4
San Luis Potosí
4.4
Sinaloa
30.2
Sonora
40.7
Tabasco
38.3
Tamaulipas
544.3
Tlaxcala
16.5
Veracruz
223.3
Yucatán
72.1
Zacatecas
24.3
Source: Authors’ calculation.
Note that the increases in own revenue under the three scenarios are very similar,
suggesting that the behavior of total revenue would not differ much from that of the
previous cases. As before, changes in states’ total revenues are shown in order to have a
57
complete picture of the situation. Table 23 shows the impact of this exempt basket
proposal on state revenues.
Table 23. Change in Total Revenues with a Local VAT Rate of 3 Percent
Considering IMCO’s Exempt Basket Proposal, 2008
State
Change (%)
Aguascalientes
1.5
Baja California
4.9
Baja California Sur
-1.5
Campeche
-0.6
Coahuila
-0.9
Colima
33.7
Chiapas
-4.3
Chihuahua
0.8
Distrito Federal
36.7
Durango
-4.1
Guanajuato
-2.5
Guerrero
-3.8
Hidalgo
-3.6
Jalisco
0.4
México
-0.6
Michoacán
-2.6
Morelos
-2.0
Nayarit
-3.4
Nuevo León
8.5
Oaxaca
-4.1
Puebla
-3.3
Querétaro
-2.9
Quintana Roo
-0.3
San Luis Potosí
-4.8
Sinaloa
-2.4
Sonora
-0.6
Tabasco
-3.9
Tamaulipas
40.6
Tlaxcala
-4.1
Veracruz
3.4
Yucatán
-2.2
Zacatecas
-3.2
Source: Authors’ calculations.
58
By reducing exemptions, total VAT collection would increase by almost 11 percent.
However, given the tax scheme proposed, shared revenues would be reduced by 5.4
percent. Under this proposal, on average the total revenue of 23 states would be reduced by
2.7 percent, while four states would increase their revenue by 14.5 percent.
Figure 27. Fiscal Autonomy Index with a Local VAT Rate Considering IMCO’s
Exempt Basket Proposal, 2008
Source: Authors’ calculations.
Even though this scenario reports an average value of the FAI of 13.4 percent (slightly
higher than the other two scenarios proposed), total state revenues would increase by 4.3
percent. Note that this increase is higher than those we reported in all previous sections.
11.2 The Case of the Personal Income Tax Surcharge
The Personal Income Tax (PIT) is another component of the RFP which, in fact, has a
greater share in non-oil tax revenue than the VAT. However, the income tax scheme is
much more complex and requires the application of different rates for personal and
corporate income according to the different tax brackets specified by law. Nonetheless, is
possible to use some assumptions to simplify the tax regime such as calculating the effect
of a personal income tax surcharge at the state level.
0%
10%
20%
30%
40%
50%
60%
Distrito Federal
Tamaulipas
Colima
Nuevo León
Chihuahua
Baja California
Quintana Roo
Querétaro
México
Sonora
Jalisco
Baja California…
Aguascalientes
Veracruz
Campeche
Sinaloa
Coahuila
Guanajuato
Zacatecas
Morelos
Hidalgo
Michoacán
Chiapas
Puebla
Yucatán
Durango
San Luis Potosí
Nayarit
Oaxaca
Guerrero
Tabasco
Tlaxcala
Potential FAI
Real FAI
59
Following Ríos et al. (2012), when calculating the PIT for Venezuelan
municipalities, we estimate income from survey data collected in 2010.
24
Using income data
from each state and a flat rate of 1 percent for all incomes above the lowest tax bracket, we
find that total collection would be close to USD 900 million in 2010. This is equivalent to 1
percent of total state revenues and 12 percent of states’ own revenues. Again, as in the case
of the VAT, if an increase in the tax rate and a broadening of the tax base is not
implemented, the final impact of a surcharge might be negative in terms of total revenues.
25
Table 24 shows the total PIT collection of by state and the percentage it represents
of its total and own revenue. Although all states to the mean regarding the PIT surcharge as
percentage of total revenues, it varies more when it comes to the percentage of own
revenues. In this case, it goes from 1.7 percent in the Distrito Federal to 17.4 in Tlaxcala.
These percentages could be increased using a different rate structure for different income
breaks. As it was proposed with the VAT, to increase efficiency this tax could also be
collected by the Federation with states deciding tax rates.
Table 24. PIT Collection with a Flat Rate of 1 Percent, 2010
State
PIT Collection
(million USD)
Percentage of total
revenues
Percentage of
own revenues
Aguascalientes
$ 11.00
1.0%
17.3%
Baja California
$ 34.17
1.3%
13.9%
Baja California Sur
$ 6.99
0.9%
8.6%
Campeche
$ 6.94
0.6%
5.9%
Coahuila
$ 23.33
0.6%
12.6%
Colima
$ 6.58
0.9%
11.9%
Chiapas
$ 18.00
0.4%
6.3%
Chihuahua
$ 27.17
0.8%
6.5%
Distrito Federal
$ 120.83
1.1%
1.7%
Durango
$ 10.33
0.6%
11.6%
Guanajuato
$ 35.17
0.9%
11.8%
Guerrero
$ 16.75
0.5%
13.5%
Hidalgo
$ 13.25
0.6%
6.7%
Jalisco
$ 70.83
1.2%
18.6%
México
$ 115.00
0.8%
7.1%
24
Encuesta Nacional de Ingreso y Gasto de los Hogares (ENIGH), 2010.
25
These calculations are not reported here because providing an accurate value requires further assumptions
and information due to the aforementioned complexity of this tax.
60
Table 24., continued
State
PIT Collection
(million USD)
Percentage of total
revenues
Percentage of
own revenues
Michoacán
$ 26.17
0.6%
14.0%
Morelos
$ 13.83
0.8%
18.7%
Nayarit
$ 9.17
0.7%
15.8%
Nuevo León
$ 54.33
1.1%
12.1%
Oaxaca
$ 19.58
0.5%
15.5%
Puebla
$ 33.25
0.7%
15.9%
Querétaro
$ 16.17
0.9%
8.4%
Quintana Roo
$ 15.25
0.8%
8.7%
San Luis Potosí
$ 20.25
0.9%
15.8%
Sinaloa
$ 21.42
0.8%
10.9%
Sonora
$ 23.25
0.7%
8.7%
Tabasco
$ 13.08
0.4%
10.9%
Tamaulipas
$ 25.42
0.8%
10.2%
Tlaxcala
$ 7.58
0.5%
17.4%
Veracruz
$ 47.00
0.6%
18.4%
Yucatán
$ 14.50
0.8%
13.5%
Zacatecas
$ 8.13
0.4%
9.8%
Total
$ 884.72
0.9%
12.5%
Source: Authors’ calculations.
11.3 Tax on Electric Consumption
Another potential source of revenue could be a tax on electricity consumption. Using data
from the Ministry of Energy at the Sistema de Información Energética, we calculate tax
collection with a 30 percent tax rate. Table 25 shows the prices per Kilowatt/hour, total
sales by each sector and the amount that would be collected in 2010 using such rates. Here
it is important to note that this calculation does not consider reductions in demand when the
tax is implemented. Although electricity consumption is considered relatively inelastic for
the average consumer, this might not be true for low-income households. For this reason,
this tax collection could be overestimated.
In total, using the 30 percent rate tax collection would be about US$ 6,231 million,
which is about 7.5 percent of total transfers to states and 7.4 percent of transfers to
municipalities. These estimates indicate that a tax on electricity consumption could be a
61
potential source of revenue for states and municipalities. An important element of this tax is
that it is aligned with environmental policies. One alternative to reduce socially sensitive
issues associated with this tax could be to allow households a certain quantity of electricity
at a zero tax rate to cover their basic needs and start taxing for every Kilowatt consumed
over this benchmark.
Table 25. Electricity Price, Total Sales and Tax Collection for Different Sectors, 2010
USD per
Kwt/hr
Total sales (million USD)
Tax collection at 30 percent tax
rate (million USD)
Residential
0.094
$ 4,544
$ 1,363
Comercial
0.155
$ 2,782
$ 835
Services
0.214
$ 1,196
$ 359
Agriculture
0.041
$ 353
$ 106
Industry
0.110
$ 11,894
$ 3,568
Medium firms
0.119
$ 8,354
$ 2,506
Large firms
0.092
$ 3,539
$ 1,062
Total
0.112
$ 20,770
$ 6,231
Source: Authors’ calculations with data from the Ministry of Energy.
12. Conclusions
Increasing sub-national revenue carries significant political costs. An increase in the
number of taxes or in the tax rate could result in potential electoral losses that sub-national
governments do not want to face and which, under the current revenue-sharing
arrangements, they can avoid.
The results show that the current tax base is not sufficient to strengthen sub-national
public finances. It needs to be broadened so that local revenues make up a greater share of
the country’s public finances. Under current legislation, even if states could collect their
full potential, this extra revenue would not have a significant impact on total tax revenues.
The situation is different for Mexican municipalities which do not adequately
exploit their current tax base, including the property tax. There is an important opportunity
to increase municipal revenue just by better exploiting current taxing authority.
On the other hand, if some taxing authority is returned to Mexican states so that
they can keep a share of central government taxes, other redistribution criteria could be
62
considered for the participaciones, since a few states would be very favored while the great
majority would be harmed, and the gap between regions would widen. These criteria
should incentivize a more efficient exploitation of local tax bases so that sub-national
governments do not return to the situation of total dependence on central government
transfers. However, proposing a new fiscal coordination system is beyond the scope of this
study.
Finally, any policy aimed at increasing sub-national revenue must be accompanied
by a proposal to improve transparency and increase accountability for sub-national
governments, to ensure that the additional resources collected are used properly.
63
References
Battese, G. and G. Corra. 1977. “Estimation of a Production Frontier Model: With
Application to the Pastoral Zone of Eastern Australia.” Australian Journal of
Agricultural Economics 21: 169-179.
Bonet, J. and G. Reyes-Tagle. 2010. “Evolución y determinantes de los ingresos propios en
los estados mexicanos: Los casos de Baja California y Michoacán.” Trimestre
Fiscal 93: 181-224. Mexico, DF, Mexico: INDETEC.
Bonet. J. and F. Rueda. 2011. “Esfuerzo fiscal en los estados mexicanos.” División de
Gestión Fiscal y Municipal. Washington, DC, United States: Inter-American
Development Bank.
Chamber of Deputies Public Finance Study Center. 2010. “Diagnóstico del Sistema Fiscal
Mexicano.” Mexico, DF, Mexico.
Coelli. T. 1995. “Estimators and Hypothesis Test for a Stochastic: A Monte Carlo
Analysis.” Journal of Productivity Analysis 6: 247-268.
---. 1996. A Guide to FRONTIER Version 4.1: A Computer Program for Frontier
Production Function Estimation.” CEPA Working Paper 96/07. Department of
Econometrics. Portland, United States: University of New England.
Díaz-Cayeros, A. and C. McLure. 2000. “Tax Assignment.” in Giugale, M. and S. Webb,
Editors. Achievements and Challenges of Fiscal Decentralization Lessons from
Mexico. Washington, DC, United States: World Bank.
González-Páramo, J. and D. Martínez. 2001. “Inversión Pública Eficiente e Impuestos
Distorsionantes en un Contexto de Equilibrio General.” Working Papers. Mexico,
DF, Mexico: Fiscal Studies Institute.
Huntington, Samuel. 1991. The Third Wave: Democratization in the Late
TwentiethCentury. Norman, OK: University of Oklahoma Press
Mexican Institute for Competitiveness. 2010. “Índice de Competitividad Urbana 2010:
Acciones Urgentes para las Ciudades del Futuro.” Mexico, DF, Mexico.
---. 2010. “Índice de Competitividad Estatal 2010: La Caja Negra del Gasto Público.”
Mexico, DF, Mexico.
Molinar, J. 1991. “Counting the Number of Parties: An Alternative Index”. The American
Political Science Review, 85 (4): 1383-1391
64
Pardinas, J. 2009. Decentralization and Budget Accountability in the Twilight of Mexican
Presidentialism. Doctoral dissertation. London, England: London School of
Economics.
Ríos, G., Ortega, F., Scrofina S. 2012. Sub-national Revenue Mobilization in Latin America
and the Caribbean Countries: The Case of Venezuela. IDB Working Paper Series:
300. Inter-American Development Bank
Trigueros, I. and A. Fernández. 2001. Análisis, Evaluación y Propuesta para una Reforma
Tributaria: Una Agenda para las Finanzas Públicas en México. Mexico, DF,
Mexico: ITAM.
Vizzio, M. 2000. “Los Sistemas de Inversión Pública en América Latina y el Caribe.” Serie
Política Fiscal. Santiago, Chile: CEPAL.
65
Appendix 1.
Aguascalientes
Juanacatlán
Tultepec
Juan C. Bonilla
Xaloztoc
Jesús María
Ocotlán
Tultitlán
Ocoyucan
Papalotla de
Xicohténcatl
San Francisco de los
Romo
Poncitlán
Villa del Carbón
Puebla
Xicohtzinco
Ensenada
Puerto Vallarta
Xonacatlán
San Andrés Cholula
Yauhquemecan
Mexicali
El Salto
Zinacantepec
San Felipe Teotlalcingo
Zacatelco
Tecate
Tlajomulco de Zúñiga
Zumpango
San Gregorio Atzompa
La Magdalena
Tlaltelulco
Tijuana
Tlaquepaque
Cuautitlán Izcalli
San Martín Texmelucan
San Damián Texoloc
Playas de Rosarito
Tonalá
Valle de Chalco
Solidaridad
San Miguel Xoxtla
San Francisco
Tetlanohcan
La Paz
Zapopan
Tonanitla
San Pedro Cholula
San Jerónimo Zacualpan
Los Cabos
Acolman
Jacona
San Salvador el Verde
San Juan Huactzinco
Campeche
Almoloya de Juárez
Morelia
Santiago Miahuatlán
San Lorenzo
Axocomanitla
Carmen
Amecameca
La Piedad
Tehuacán
Santa Ana Nopalucan
Acuña
Apaxco
Tarímbaro
Tepatlaxco de Hidalgo
Santa Apolonia Teacalco
Arteaga
Atenco
Uruapan
Tlaltenango
Santa Catarina Ayometla
Castaños
Atizapán de Zaragoza
Zamora
Corregidora
Santa Cruz Quilehtla
Frontera
Atlautla
Atlatlahucan
Huimilpan
Santa Isabel Xiloxoxtla
Matamoros
Axapusco
Ayala
El Marqués
Alvarado
Monclova
Ayapango
Cuautla
Querétaro
Amatlán de los Reyes
Nava
Calimaya
Cuernavaca
San Juan del Río
Atzacan
Piedras Negras
Coacalco de Berriozábal
Emiliano Zapata
Isla Mujeres
Banderilla
Ramos Arizpe
Cocotitlán
Huitzilac
Othón P. Blanco
Boca del Río
Saltillo
Coyotepec
Jiutepec
Benito Juárez
Camerino Z. Mendoza
Torreón
Cuautitlán
Temixco
Solidaridad
Cazones
Armería
Chalco
Tepoztlán
Ciudad Fernández
Coatepec
Colima
Chapultepec
Tlayacapan
Rioverde
Coatzacoalcos
Comala
Chiautla
Xochitepec
San Luis Potosí
Coatzintla
Coquimatlán
Chicoloapan
Yautepec
Soledad de Graciano
Sánchez
Córdoba
Cuauhtémoc
Chiconcuac
Yecapixtla
Ahome
Cosoleacaque
Manzanillo
Chimalhuacán
Xalisco
Culiacán
Chinameca
Tecomán
Ecatepec de Morelos
Tepic
Mazatlán
Emiliano Zapata
Villa de Álvarez
Ecatzingo
Bahía de Banderas
Cajeme
Fortín
Chiapa de Corzo
Huehuetoca
Apodaca
Empalme
Huiloapan
San Cristóbal de las
Casas
Hueypoxtla
Cadereyta Jiménez
Guaymas
Ixhuatlancillo
Tapachula
Huixquilucan
García
Hermosillo
Ixhuatlán del Sureste
Tuxtla Gutiérrez
Isidro Fabela
San Pedro Garza García
Navojoa
Ixtaczoquitlán
Aldama
Ixtapaluca
General Escobedo
Nogales
Xalapa
Aquiles Serdán
Jaltenco
Guadalupe
Cárdenas
Jáltipan
Chihuahua
Jilotzingo
Juárez
Centro
Jilotepec
66
Delicias
Juchitepec
Monterrey
Comalcalco
Mariano Escobedo
Juárez
Lerma
Salinas Victoria
Huimanguillo
Medellín
Durango
Melchor Ocampo
San Nicolás de los Garza
Macuspana
Minatitlán
Gómez Palacio
Metepec
Santa Catarina
Nacajuca
Nogales
Lerdo
Mexicaltzingo
Santiago
Altamira
Orizaba
Celaya
Naucalpan de Juárez
Oaxaca de Juárez
Ciudad Madero
Oteapan
Guanajuato
Nezahualcóyotl
Salina Cruz
Matamoros
Pánuco
Irapuato
Nextlalpan
San Agustín de las
Juntas
Nuevo Laredo
Papantla
León
Nicolás Romero
San Agustín Yatareni
Reynosa
Poza Rica de Hidalgo
Pénjamo
Nopaltepec
San Andrés Huayápam
Río Bravo
Pueblo Viejo
Purísima del Rincón
Ocoyoacac
San Antonio de la Cal
Tampico
Rafael Delgado
Salamanca
Otumba
San Bartolo Coyotepec
Victoria
Rafael Lucio
San Francisco del
Rincón
Otzolotepec
San Blas Atempa
Amaxac de Guerrero
Río Blanco
Silao
Ozumba
San Jacinto Amilpas
Apetatitlán de Antonio
Carvajal
Tihuatlán
Acapulco de Juárez
Papalotla
Ánimas Trujano
Apizaco
Tlalnelhuayocan
Coyuca de Benítez
La Paz
San Juan Bautista
Tuxtepec
Cuaxomulco
Tlilapan
Zihuatanejo de Azueta
Rayón
San Lorenzo Cacaotepec
Chiautempan
Veracruz
Atitalaquia
San Antonio la Isla
San Pablo Etla
Ixtacuixtla de Mariano
Matamoros
Yanga
Atotonilco de Tula
San Martín de las
Pirámides
San Sebastián Tutla
Mazatecochco de José
María Morelos
Zaragoza
Cuautepec de Hinojosa
San Mateo Atenco
Santa Cruz Amilpas
Contla de Juan Cuamatzi
Nanchital de Lázaro
Cárdenas del Río
Epazoyucan
Tecámac
Santa Cruz Xoxocotlán
Tepetitla de Lardizábal
Conkal
Mineral del Monte
Temamatla
Santa Lucía del Camino
Acuamanala de Miguel
Hidalgo
Kanasín
Pachuca de Soto
Temascalapa
Santa María Atzompa
Nativitas
Mérida
Mineral de la Reforma
Tenango del Aire
Santa María Coyotepec
Panotla
Ucú
San Agustín Tlaxiaca
Teoloyucán
Santa María del Tule
San Pablo del Monte
Umán
Santiago Tulantepec de
Lugo Guerrero
Teotihuacán
Santo Domingo
Tehuantepec
Santa Cruz Tlaxcala
Guadalupe
Tizayuca
Tepetlaoxtoc
Santo Domingo
Tomaltepec
Tenancingo
Zacatecas
Tlahuelilpan
Tepetlixpa
Tlalixtac de Cabrera
Teolocholco
Tlaxcoapan
Tepotzotlán
Villa de Zaachila
Tepeyanco
Tula de Allende
Tequixquiac
Amozoc
Tetla de la Solidaridad
Tulancingo de Bravo
Texcoco
Coronango
Tetlatlahuca
Zapotlán de Juárez
Tezoyuca
Cuautlancingo
Tlaxcala
Zempoala
Tlalmanalco
Chiautzingo
Tocatlán
Guadalajara
Tlalnepantla de Baz
Domingo Arenas
Totolac
Ixtlahuacán de los
Membrillos
Toluca
Huejotzingo
Tzompantepec
67
Appendix 2. Overview of the Fiscal Situation in the Central Government
Excluding oil revenue, the central government is responsible for the most lucrative revenue
sources: income taxes, value-added tax (VAT), special taxes on production and services,
and trade tariffs.
Tax revenue in Mexico consists mainly of two taxes: the income tax and the VAT.
Production and Services Special Tax (IEPS) shows a variable pattern because of its reliance
on gasoline prices, becoming a subsidy when international prices are very high, as in 2008.
Current gasoline pricing schemes aggravate the volatility of the fiscal dependency
on oil. The IEPS tax on gasoline becomes a subsidy when oil prices increase, as shown in
Figure 28 for 2008, when government gasoline subsidies were equivalent to 18 percent of
total tax revenue.
Figure 28. Tax Revenue Structure
Source: Chamber of Deputies Public Finance Study Center.
In 2008, income taxes accounted for more than 50 percent of non-oil tax revenue.
The second most important source of non-oil tax revenue was the value added tax,
accounting for 38 percent.
-20%
0%
20%
40%
60%
80%
100%
1980 1983 1986 1990 1994 1995 1999 2002 2005 2007 2008
Others Trade tax Production and services Special tax Value added tax Revenue tax
68
Figure 29. Composition of Non-oil Tax Revenue, 2008
Source: Treasury Ministry (SHCP).
In Mexico, income taxes can be divided into three groups: personal, corporate, and
payroll. In recent years, revenue from the payroll tax has been rising. In 2002 it was about
24.7 percent of total income tax collection, while in 2008 it accounted for 48 percent of the
total.
Income tax is progressive: the lowest income earners do not pay this tax and in fact
have a negative tax rate that works like a wage subsidy. As the level of income increases,
so does the tax rate. The highest tax bracket is 30 percent of gross personal income.
However, this tax has a high evasion rate. Research by El Colegio de México, CIDE, and
ITAM has found that personal income tax evasion ranges from 20 to 80 percent of potential
revenue.
Mexico has a great potential of increasing the amount collected through the VAT.
Between 1997 and 2010, the VAT rate stood at 15 percent. In 2010, it was increased to 16
percent. Mexico still has one of the lowest rates among OECD countries as well as one of
the lowest levels of collected revenue.
52%
38%
4%
3%
3%
Income tax Value added tax Production and services tax Tariffs Other taxes
69
Figure 30. Value-added Tax Rates for OECD countries, 2010
Source: IMCO using data from OECD 2010.
In Mexico, some products are not taxed or are exempted from the VAT, such as
foodstuffs and medicines. Moreover, Mexico has a special VAT regime in regions
bordering the United States. Research by ITAM (Trigueros and Fernández, 2001) estimates
that tax evasion represents 20 to 23 percent of potential revenue, equivalent to 1 percent of
GDP. These conditions would allow the country to increase the portion of the VAT in total
revenue both in absolute terms and as a percentage of GDP.
0.00
5.00
10.00
15.00
20.00
25.00
30.00
ISL
HUN
SWE
POL
IRL
CZE
PRT
CHL
GRC
SVK
Prom
MEX
LUX
AUS
CHE
JPN
%
70
Figure 31. Value-added Tax Revenue as Percentage of GDP, 1980-2008
Source: IMCO using data from OECD revenue statistics.
0
2
4
6
8
10
12
1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008
% of GDP
Value-added tax revenue
Deenmark Finland France Ireland
Mexico Sweeden Korea OECD average